The Return of Stock-Based Compensation on Wall Street

Everything old is new again, as Yves

Smith points out with respect to UBS’s bonuses. Apparently

the poor Swiss bankers won’t get cash this year: everything above a measly $750,000

is going to be paid in stock. Is this kind of tight-fistedness going to backfire?

Not if Goldman Sachs is any indication. Back when it was still a partnership,

Smith says, "the line at Goldman was the partners lived poor and died rich."

Indeed, I can see other banks looking jealously at UBS and trying their hardest

to follow suit. It makes very little sense for compensation to be structured

so that you earn loads of money in 2006 for piling on too much risk, and then

get fired in 2007 when those bets go bad. (It makes even less sense if you’re

then compensated

in 2007 all over again for your 2006 "performance".) Much better

that you should earn relatively little in 2006, but get lots of equity in the

firm which pays off in spades if your earnings turn out to be non-fictional.

Posted in pay | Comments Off on The Return of Stock-Based Compensation on Wall Street

Extra Credit, Tuesday Edition

Citi’s

giant write-downs: What did it know, and when did it know it?

Blackstone’s

M&A Biz Provides No Relief: You thought Blackstone was an M&A advisory

shop as well as a private-equity firm? Turns out, not so much. Also:

Blackstone

posts loss from IPO charges: "Blackstone is starting to go long the

subprime market". Is that smart, given its extant commercial real-estate

exposure?

Nouriel

Roubini’s latest recession call: "Expect Q4 growth to be 1% or below

and this growth further to accelerate into negative territory by H1 of 2008."

Is this a meme? Me,

on November 4: "In the Sachs vs Easterly debate, I come down on the

side of, shall we say, Paul Collier." Jagdish

Bhagwati, on November 7: "I disagree with Sachs and Easterly, for opposed

reasons… I am more in tune with Paul Collier".

Saudi Prince Alwaleed Buys a Private

A380

The

11 most bicycle-friendly cities in the world: The USA does surprisingly

well, with four. Interestingly, San Francisco comes in 8th, despite its hills.

Fake

Prada fuels Senegal’s Muslim brotherhood

Posted in remainders | Comments Off on Extra Credit, Tuesday Edition

E*Trade: In Defense of Prashant Bhatia

Just as one shouldn’t shout "fire" in a crowded theater, one shouldn’t

shout "run on the bank" in an analyst’s report. If you do that, as

Citigroup’s Prashant

Bhatia notoriously did in his report on E*Trade, you risk your report turning

into a self-fulfilling

prophecy. After all, no bank is immune to a bank run.

At the same time, however, I think it’s rash to simply blame Bhatia and call

him "irresponsible" for publishing what was actually a pretty sober

piece of analysis. The key datapoint: half of E*Trade’s deposits, or $15

billion, are in accounts that contain more than $100,000, and are therefore

not insured by the FDIC. If I was an E*Trade depositor, and I had more than

$100,000 in the bank, and I saw that E*Trade was announcing subprime write-downs

of unknown size, then I wouldn’t need Prashant Bhatia to tell me to

move my money somewhere a little bit safer.

If I were E*Trade, then, I wouldn’t be running around shooting the messenger,

I would be running around spending as much money as it took to buy private insurance

on all of my deposits over and above the FDIC cap. Either that, or I would be

simply trying to sell myself to someone rather better-capitalized.

As for Bhatia, he called it right. There are a million different things which

can cause a bank run, and analysts’ reports are hardly top of the list. What’s

more, for the time being there’s still no evidence of any bank run at all. Although

that might change tomorrow, when depositors start seeing the headlines. Even

then, however, the proximate cause of the bank run would be the drop in the

share price, not Bhatia’s report per se. As we’ve seen with shares

from Crocs to Sotheby’s, there’s no shortage of stocks which turn out to be

just waiting for an excuse to crater. E*Trade turned out to be one of them,

and that’s not Bhatia’s fault.

Posted in banking, stocks | Comments Off on E*Trade: In Defense of Prashant Bhatia

Earnings Datapoint of the Day

Ken Rogoff:

"If you are earning $540,000 an hour, it does not take too long to save

up to buy an apartment, even in London."

The sum in question is the minimum amount you need to earn in order

to count as one of the top nine earners in the United States.

Posted in wealth | Comments Off on Earnings Datapoint of the Day

Counting Foreign Students

Dani Rodrik gives

the NYT a slap on the wrist today for its article

saying that foreign students "added to the economy" to the tune of

$14.5 billion last year. The article was based on a press

release from the Institute of International Education; the offending figure

comes in the 12th of 12 paragraphs.

The obvious question, then, is why the NYT led with the rather fuzzy and meaningless

$14.5 billion number, rather than the much more germane news, headlined in the

release, that foreign enrollment in US universities is finally rising again

after falling for some time. I can’t say I can think of any good reason: can

you?

Posted in economics, Media | Comments Off on Counting Foreign Students

Holiday Party Datapoint of the Day

Battalia

Winston runs its annual survey:

85 percent of businesses will be conducting some type of holiday celebration

this year, a nine percent decrease from 2006… In addition, while a majority

(54%) of parties will be evening events and 70 percent of companies will be

serving alcohol, these findings represent a 20 percent and 15 percent drop

from 2006, respectively.

(In one of those wonderful aptonymic coincidences, I really did find this via

Nazareth.)

Posted in holidays | Comments Off on Holiday Party Datapoint of the Day

When Athletes IPO

Remember the jock

exchange that Michael Lewis wrote about in the first issue of Portfolio?

The idea was that an exchange could be set up where the assets traded were not

shares in companies but rather shares in athletes. Well, it hasn’t happened

yet – and if Formula One star Lewis Hamilton has any say in the matter,

it might not happen at all. For why bother with the ghetto of a jock exchange

when you can simply list

yourself directly on a major stock exchange? Cole Moreton reports:

The 22-year-old is apparently considering floating himself on the stockmarket…

His father, Anthony, and specialist advisers are considering a range of business

moves. In one remarkable plan, a new company would be set up with the driver

as both its major asset and shareholder – and sell off 10 per cent of

its stock on the London stock exchange for about $100m.

That would give him a lump sum now – before he has a chance to crash

his car at high speed, lose his nerve or go off the rails as a result of the

luxurious new life he can enjoy as a superstar.

The results of England’s experiment in listing football clubs were, to put

it mildly, unspectacular; most of them have been delisted by now. But at least

a football club can last indefinitely; stock in an individual athlete, by contrast,

is by definition a wasting asset. Investors would buy it not in the hope of

capital gains, but rather to reap as much in the way of dividends as possible

before the athlete in question’s career came to an end. While most stocks hold

out at least the potential of massive upside, then, an athlete’s stock would

probably have more downside than upside. Which would make it a good investment

only for the most sophisticated of investors.

Posted in sports | Comments Off on When Athletes IPO

When is a Hedge Not a Hedge?

Allison

Pyburn has some numbers on just how much the notorious "super-senior"

tranches of subprime-backed CDOs are actually worth in the market. It’s probably

no surprise that the junior tranches are changing hands in "the high single

digits," but more to the point the super-senior tranches, she says, are

fetching no more than 60 cents on the dollar, which of course corresponds to

a 40% write-down. By contrast, she says, Merrill’s latest write-down was just

19% on its super-senior CDO holdings.

These numbers are scary enough that there’s a serious chance of a domino effect.

Banks for instance were able to hedge their CDO holdings by insuring them against

loss – but now the insurers are at risk of going bust. The titles of two

blog entries on this subject say it all: "So

Much For Being Hedged" and "Another

word for hedged… leveraged".

We’ve already seen something along these lines at Morgan

Stanley, where the "hedge" on its bearish mortgage-bond bet seems

to have been much riskier than the original bet itself. But I have to say that

the Morgan Stanley losses don’t make a lot of sense to me. For all the talk

of "negative convexity", the trade looks as though it was after

all a simple long-senior, short-junior play. If you really wanted to make a

bearish bet on mortgage bonds, why on earth would you fund it with a long position

in mortgage bonds, of all things? Why not use emerging-market debt,

or Treasury bonds, or something – anything – which wouldn’t go down

when mortgage debt fell in value?

Posted in bonds and loans | Comments Off on When is a Hedge Not a Hedge?

Next Rate Move: Up And Down at the Same Time?

Steve

Waldman, provocative as ever, resuscitates a 2002 speech

by Ben Bernanke, wherein the future Fed chairman notes that the central bank

has more tools at its disposal than simply raising or lowering the Fed funds

rate. Specifically, he says, when liquidity premiums start to spike, as is happening

right now, the Fed can "offer fixed-term loans to banks at low or zero

interest, with a wide range of private assets (including, among others, corporate

bonds, commercial paper, bank loans, and mortgages) deemed eligible as collateral."

Steve takes this argument to its logical conclusion. Why does the Fed’s discount

rate always have to be higher than the Fed funds rate? "Suppose the Fed

were to offer to lend against specific sorts of collateral at a negative spread

to Federal Funds," he writes, and suppose that collateral were the nasty

products presently stinking up the banking system – RMBS, CDOs, that kind

of thing. To all intents and purposes, the Fed would be offering to buy those

assets from the beleaguered banks, which would help address the credit crunch

and the financial-sector problems which have driven the Fed’s last two rate

cuts. And if those problems were addressed, then the Fed could actually raise

the Fed funds rate in order to help contain inflation.

The Fed would have its cake and eat it too. It would promote full employment

by stopping a dangerous financial crisis in its tracks. It would promote price

stability by hiking interest rates to support the purchasing power (and FX

value, and commodity value) of the dollar.

There would be some danger that, even with the banks bailed out, interest

rate hikes would slow the economy. But that hazard is unusually small now,

because the binding constraint on lending is not the Fed-set interest rate,

but concerns about creditworthiness and quality of collateral… a bad situation

would be made very little worse by a moderate rate hike, if the financial

sector could withstand it.

Steve does note that there are very good moral-hazard reasons not

to do this. But once a house is burning, it’s a bit late for lectures about

not smoking in bed: the important thing is to put out the fire. In terms of

monetary policy, one way of doing that would be to bring the discount rate down

for certain types of collateral, even as the Fed funds rate could be raised

upwards. As a result, the unwise banks would be rewarded, while the better-run

banks would be punished. But the financial system and the economy more generally

might still benefit.

Posted in fiscal and monetary policy | Comments Off on Next Rate Move: Up And Down at the Same Time?

The Economist Debates: Bloggers Win!

The Economist has brought its

debate series to New York, and the first two debates took place in the magnificent

Gotham Hall on Saturday. The first one was on wealth and happiness, and pitched

two bloggers (Tyler Cowen and Will Wilkinson) against two A-list economists

(Betsey Stevenson and Jeff Sachs). Without going into too much detail (you can

get that from Cowen’s

commenters or from Will),

the bloggers won: many congratulations to them.

The second debate was on religion and politics. Afterwards, the Economist laid

on some cocktails, where Stevenson’s equally A-list husband, Justin Wolfers,

pondered Pascal’s Wager. If you believe there’s anything at all to religion,

he noted (and possibly if you don’t), the biggest risk one runs is the risk

that you belong to the wrong religion. So how would you go about hedging that?

Justin’s suggestion: have lots of children, and bring each of them up in a different

religion. You might not make it to heaven, but at least you’re maximizing your

chances that at least one of your children will.

Both debates were successful and enjoyable, which means I think that there

will certainly be more of them. Interestingly, there doesn’t seem to be any

shortage of New Yorkers willing to spend between $20 and $40 to while away a

large chunk of their Saturday afternoon listening to debating points. Don’t

they know they can read as many blogs as they like for free?

Posted in economics | Comments Off on The Economist Debates: Bloggers Win!

Ugliness in Industrial Design

Sometimes, good design is good business. Just look at Apple. And sometimes,

bad design is bad business: look at Detroit. But sometimes, the beauty of the

object plays precisely zero role in purchasing decisions. That’s obviously the

case for things that aren’t ever seen: computer chips, for instance. But it’s

also the case for really big objects which can be described as "hideous",

"the worst-looking piece of major industrial design of the past 50 years",

"shamelessly, needlessly ugly", and "an aesthetic abomination".

Objects, that is, like the Airbus

A380.

When airlines choose between Boeing and Airbus, they don’t let the aesthetics

of the exterior drive their decision. And passengers, too, care only about the

interior, not the exterior, of the jet. But that doesn’t stop Patrick Smith

making an impassioned plea for beauty in aviation design:

Is it true, to cite a quote attributed to an Airbus engineer some years ago,

that "Air does not yield to style"? Jet age romantics recall the

provocative curves of machines like the Caravelle; the urbane, needle-nosed

superiority of Concorde; the Gothic surety of the 727. You’re telling us that

planes need to be boring, or worse, in the name of efficiency and economy.

No, they don’t. The state-of-the-art Boeing 787 is evidence enough of that.

Let’s take Smith at face value here, and assume that he’s right. Is it then

incumbent upon Airbus to build a beautiful plane? If not for the sake of profits,

then just for its own sake? My feeling is that any aesthetic stylings which

detract from an airplane’s cost-effectiveness are a very bad idea. After all,

a tiny change in an airplane’s profile can cause an enormous increase in construction

or jet-fuel costs.

That said, however, I also feel that great designers, of airplanes or anything

else, are generally incapable of producing something truly ugly (although some

things, like electrical substations, seem to be simply immune to beauty). Airbus

is a notorious europudding of a company – the classic place where all

decisions are made by committee. I do hold out some romantic hope that an ugly

design can never be the best design; that something truly efficient is likely

also to be good-looking. Maybe the A380 isn’t ugly because it’s efficient.

And just maybe there’s a solution out there which would have made it both better-looking

and cheaper to construct and operate.

(Via Abnormal

Returns)

Posted in design | Comments Off on Ugliness in Industrial Design

Ben Stein Watch: November 11, 2007

Ben

Stein’s big idea this week is that if banks have taken large losses, their

board members should be held responsible. It’s something I’ve

said in the past, so I should agree with him, right? But this is Stein,

of course, which means that even when he’s right, he’s right for the wrong reasons.

Take banks’ losses on CDOs. What happened there? Banks such as Citigroup and

Merrill Lynch would bundle up lots of bonds, many of them backed by subprime

mortgages. They would then take the income from those bonds, and split it into

tranches, much like the income from mortgages is aggregated and tranched in

mortgage-backed securities. They would then sell the tranches to investors attracted

by the high yields on offer, and they would make healthy profits by charging

a fee for their services structuring the CDO in the first place.

But there was a problem. It turned out to be quite easy to sell the lower-rated

tranches of the CDOs, and even the weakest of the AAA-rated tranches. But at

the very top of the waterfall, there was a large chunk of so-called "super-senior"

notes, which yielded so little that no one seemed particularly interested in

buying them. As a result, the banks structuring the CDOs tended to keep those

super-senior tranches on their own books – an activity which they thought

carried negligible risk, since the debt was, as we used to say in England, as

safe as houses.

When houses turned out to be not very safe, those super-senior tranches went

from being safe to being unsellable at pretty much any price. You could try

to look to something like the ABX index to get an idea of what the market considered

them to be worth, but for many

reasons the ABX is an atrocious guide to the value of super-senior CDO tranches.

All the same, those CDO tranches are now clearly not valued at par, and so the

banks concerned, responsibly enough, have written down the value of those tranches

by many billions of dollars.

Now, here’s Stein:

Why didn’t the directors ask the chiefs, “Gee, how can you continue

to earn a far higher rate of return on debt than the market rate? How are

you defying gravity this way? Can it last?”

Why were the questions not asked?

Well, Ben, the questions were not asked precisely because the super-senior

CDO tranches weren’t earning more than the market rate: that’s why

no one was particularly interested in buying them. They were considered ultrasafe,

ultraboring, low-yielding assets. The banks were happy to hold on to them because

they were safe and because they came with hefty fee income attached. But if

no one structuring these things foresaw that they might plunge in value, it’s

a bit much to ask directors to be so prescient.

What the directors should certainly have been doing is keeping an eye on total

CDO exposure – that’s where the Merrill directors fell asleep at the wheel.

But the number they should have been looking at was the rate of increase of

total CDO assets, not the spread between market interest rates and

the yields on CDOs. Looking at that spread would have told them nothing.

Stein doesn’t stop there, of course. He accuses Merrill of being "P.C."

in its choice of directors, stopping just short of making the same accusation

about the chairman of the board in particular, who of course was African-American.

And he is also unimpressed by Bob Rubin:

When I saw that Citi had taken a bath in collateralized debt obligations

and subprime, and saw that Robert E. Rubin had been on the board in a major

position and had failed to stop the train wreck, I was staggered. And now

he has been named chairman. He couldn’t protect Citi’s stockholders,

and now he’s in charge? And let’s remember, he was Treasury secretary

when we had the first part of one of the worst bubbles in stock market history.

What on earth are the Citi directors thinking?

Clearly, everybody on Citi’s board "failed to stop the train wreck"

– should they all have been defenestrated along with Chuck Prince? And

I really don’t see what Rubin, as Treasury secretary, can or should have done

to prevent a stock-market bubble. It may or may not be fair to blame Alan Greenspan,

who was in charge of monetary policy and margin requirements, for that bubble.

Rubin, by contrast, was in charge of fiscal policy, which has precious little

effect on stock prices.

Stein finishes off with an appeal to patriotism, implicitly accusing Rubin

and the other board members of immorality:

It certainly hurts to spend day after day, as I did this fall, at Walter

Reed Army Medical Center — where the incredibly brave wounded soldiers

from Iraq and Afghanistan learn about walking and eating without their natural

legs and arms — and to realize that the America for which they’re

fighting is led in so many arenas, especially the money one, by such weak,

disappointing specimens.

It’s high time that the America for which soldiers sacrifice so much

is run on a moral standard more like theirs.

Do you hear that, Mr Rubin? You should behave, at Citigroup, much as US soldiers

behave in Iraq and Afghanistan. Your thank-you letter for this advice should

be sent to Ben Stein, c/o the New York Times, 620 Eighth Avenue, NY 10018. Hop

to it, before more "fresh tears keep the ground damp" at Arlington

National Cemetery.

Posted in ben stein watch | Comments Off on Ben Stein Watch: November 11, 2007

Extra Credit, Weekend Edition

Prince

Alwaleed: Why Chuck had to go

Redstone:

‘If Content Is King, Copyright Is Its Castle’: The codger comes out swinging.

Who’s Afraid of a Falling

Dollar?: "For the vast majority of the country, a ‘strong dollar’ is

more like a ‘strong influenza virus’ – something to be avoided whenever possible."

James

Lockhart vs Andrew Cuomo: Tanta referees.

Radiohead

Criticizes Outside Sales Figures

Posted in remainders | Comments Off on Extra Credit, Weekend Edition

Deciphering Auction Results

In the wake of my entry

yesterday about auction houses’ estimates and reserves, Rik Pike of Christie’s

has been very helpful in clearing a few things up for me. For one thing, there’s

no doubt that estimates refer to the hammer price, and not to the total

price paid – which is the number reported by the press and by the auction

houses themselves in the wake of the sale. "Christie’s sets pre-sale estimates

and reserves without premium, and reports on post-sale results with premium,

as this reflects the final price the buyer pays for the lot," he says.

So what would this mean, I asked, in the case of a painting like the one I

talked about yesterday? Let’s say it was actually sold at a hammer price of

$25 million, and let’s say it carried a pre-sale estimate of $28 million to

$35 million. Once you add in the auction house’s commission, the total price

paid comes to just over $28 million, which brings it into the range of the estimate.

"The standard industry practice is to consider the final price paid for

the lot as being in excess of $28 million — the actual dollars paid,"

says Pike.

In other words, "standard industry practice" essentially boosts all

bids by between 12% and 25%, bringing them that much closer to their pre-sale

estimates. The $28 million estimate on the painting gets compared to the $28

million actually paid for it, and not to the $25 million bid for it. Let’s say

you read a story,

then, saying something like this:

Sotheby’s sale totaled $269.7 million, well under its $355.6 million

low estimate.

It’s worth remembering, in that case, that the sale total includes

the auction-house commission, while the estimate excludes it. On the

other hand, it’s also worth remembering that adding up the estimates assumes

that every last painting sells, something which very rarely happens.

But what if the bidding on a painting reaches $25 million and the painting

goes unsold at that price, as happened at Sotheby’s this week? Can we assume

that the $25 million bid was real? No. Before the auction, the auctioneer will

read out a disclaimer something like this:

Bidders should note that the auctioneer may open bidding on any lot below

the reserve by placing a bid on behalf of the seller. I, as the auctioneer,

may continue to bid on behalf of the seller up to the amount of the reserve

either by placing consecutive bids or by placing bids in response to other

bidders.

If the reserve was at or above $25 million, then, that bid might well be "on

behalf of the seller", or, as it’s more commonly known, "off the chandelier".

This is entirely kosher, in the world of auctions. If you’re physically in the

sale room and you’ve hung around a few art auctions, it’s often pretty obvious

which paintings got real bids below the reserve price, and which didn’t. But

it’s impossible to know for sure.

While I’m at it, I should also answer the question left by Laura, in the comments

of yesterday’s blog:

It seems unfair to me that an action house can have a reserve price and so

be protected from the downside, but have unlimited upside potential subject

to market demand. I’m curious if you have any analysis to offer of this situation.

What does it do to the art market over all? Are there any comparable situations

in the financial markets? Or is this just a mechanism of a free market in

which no seller is ever forced to sell at a lower price than he thinks his

goods are worth?

What Laura forgets here is that the auction house is not the seller of the

object: it’s only the middle-man. Unless it has offered a guarantee (which is

a whole other discussion entirely), it has no downside at all. The worst that

can happen is that the painting fails to sell and the auction house therefore

receives no commission.

But yes, in general any market price is a clearing price: it’s the

level at which both a buyer is willing to buy and at which

a seller is willing to sell. In that sense, auction prices are like any other

financial market – a market price, pretty much by definition, has to be

acceptable to both buyer and seller, otherwise there is not trade, no transaction,

no price. The function of the reserve price in an auction is to ensure that

the final price is acceptable to the seller.

Posted in art | Comments Off on Deciphering Auction Results

Secrecy in Book Publishing

Between the issues dated January 8 and November 12, nothing by Malcom Gladwell

appeared in the New Yorker, and nothing appeared on his blog,

either. Gladwell finally broke

his silence on Monday:

I took a little break from blogging, to work on my new book. But now it’s

almost finished, and I’m

back in the New Yorker this week.

Gladwell gives no hint as to what his new book will be about; instead, Kottke

has the scoop.

What interests me about all this is the secrecy and the lack of transparency

involved. Not only was the subject of Gladwell’s book a secret; even the very

fact that he was writing one was kept well under wraps. The whole thing smells

as either though Gladwell or his publisher was in fully-fledged I’ve-got-a-great-idea-and-I-don’t-want-anybody-to-steal-it

mode.

This is actually rather common. A friend of mine recently quit her job, for

instance, to start a new venture; when I asked what it was, she replied via

email:

I can’t tell you because I think it is too good an idea!

Similarly, when someone like Gawker Media’s Nick Denton decides to launch a

new blog, he works on it in utmost secrecy until the day it goes live.

The opposite tack is much less common, but last month very succesful venture

capitalist Fred Wilson wrote a blog entry headlined "Playing

Your Hand With Your Cards Turned Up":

I do not believe we’ve made an investment in our fund without me talking

about it, using it, and thinking out loud about it on this blog…

Blogging about things we are looking at is all part of the transparent firm

that we are trying to create. We want people to know what we are up to…

We try to be very open about what we are looking for, what we are looking

at, and when we invest we like to be open about the reasons we did so. We

formed our firm four years ago, raised our first fund three years ago, and

in that short time we have been able to establish a significant presence in

our sector. We’d never have been able to do that if we had been playing with

our cards turned upside down.

What would have happened if Gladwell had announced that he was taking book

leave, if he had told everybody what the subject of his book was going to be,

and if he had blogged about that subject continually while writing the book?

For one thing, he would have got some interesting ideas from visitors to his

blog. For another thing, he would essentially have injected the ideas behind

the book virally into the public’s subconsciousness, quite possibly making the

public more receptive to the book when it finally came out.

The possible downsides? Well, someone else might have tried to write a book

on the same subject more quickly, and get it out before Gladwell’s book appeared.

Which seems improbable to me, given that (a) no author wants to be seen as treading

on Gladwell’s publicly-announced turf; (b) no publisher wants to be seen as

treading on Gladwell’s publicly-announced turf; and (c) in any case trying to

turn a book around so quickly would be extremely difficult. More to the point,

even if that did happen, there’s no reason that it wouldn’t merely whet the

public’s appetite for Gladwell’s book, rather than cannibalize its sales.

The other possible downside is that the public might get bored with Gladwell’s

idea by the time the book came out, and figure that they already understood

most of what he wanted to say, and if they didn’t then they could always read

his blog entries for free rather than pay good money for the book. But you can’t

copyright ideas, and the ideas behind Gladwell’s book are all going to enter

the public domain the minute that the first reviews start coming out.

In general, when it comes to blogs or books or most things along those lines,

the idea is the easy part: it’s the execution which is hard. The reason that

Gladwell is so successful is that he’s extremely good at communicating the ideas

of others to a mass audience: which specific ideas he decides to communicate

is really much less important. Similarly, there’s no shortage of gadget blogs

out there, but it takes a lot of work and a lot of writers to create something

as important and influential as Gizmodo.

I suspect that the secrecy surrounding such projects serves more to make their

principals feel important than it does to serve any real purpose. Books are

not particularly interactive things, but as the examples of Freakonomics

and Steven Johnson and Chris

Anderson show, there’s a lot of upside to transparency and two-way conversation.

Sooner rather than later, I suspect, the secrecy surrounding book projects like

Gladwell’s be a thing of the past.

Posted in Media | Comments Off on Secrecy in Book Publishing

Stiglitz’s US Datapoints

Vanity Fair gives Joe Stiglitz 4,000

words in its December issue, and he delivers what Andrew Leonard describes

as "a stinging, biting, razor-sharp dissection of everything George W.

Bush has done wrong as the keeper of the American economy". A few datapoints

jumped out at me:

  • A young male in his 30s today has an income, adjusted for inflation, that

    is 12 percent less than what his father was making 30 years ago.

  • 5.3 million more Americans are living in poverty now than were living in

    poverty when Bush became president.

  • Agricultural subsidies were doubled between 2002 and 2005.
  • Between March 2006 and March 2007 personal-bankruptcy rates soared more

    than 60 percent.

This is not the whole story, to be sure. But it is depressing, all the same.

Posted in economics | Comments Off on Stiglitz’s US Datapoints

Carina: The 18-Notch Downgrade

You wondered what would happen when a CDO was forced to liquidate? Now

you know:

The ratings on the most senior class of Carina CDO Ltd. were lowered to BB,

two levels below investment grade, from AAA, while another AAA class was slashed

18 steps to CCC-minus. The chance of material losses to note holders is high,

New York-based S&P said.

Carina is a CDO which was born in September 2006. When it failed an over-collateralization

ratio test, the senior debt holders triggered

their option to liquidate. S&P said the proceeds would be sold at "what

will most assuredly be depressed prices".

You can be sure that the vultures are circling Carina already: this is the

kind of event that distressed-debt investors live for. What’s interesting is

that S&P said that the AAA debt would only have been cut by two notches

had the CDO not decided to liquidate: they clearly reckon that the structure

is still reasonably sound. But if that was really the case, one would imagine

that the senior debt holders would simply have tried to sell their CDO tranches

in the secondary market, rather than liquidating the entire vehicle.

Posted in bonds and loans | Comments Off on Carina: The 18-Notch Downgrade

Emilio Botin for Citigroup CEO!

Chalk up another victory for Santander’s Emilio Botín. When I said

last month that he was the big winner in the Battle of ABN Amro, I was concentrating

mainly on Banco Real, the Brazilian bank that Santander now owns. But Santander

also ended up with ABN’s unloved Italian arm, Antonveneta. ABN overpaid for

the bank in 2005, after getting caught up in a bidding war with Italy’s BPI,

and ended up buying

the bank at a valuation of €7.6 billion. By the time Santander got

it, two years later, the Spaniards valued the franchise at only €6.6 billion,

including its respected Interbanca merchant banking business.

But there’s a sucker born every minute, and Botín has now managed to

sell Antonveneta, sans Interbanca, for an astonishing €9 billion

to Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena. And boy is the market punishing

MPS for agreeing to such a ridiculous acquisition: MPS is now valued at

little more than €9 billion itself. Meanwhile, check out the chart of Santander’s

share price: the Spanish bank is now worth $136 billion, compared to a market

cap of $160 billion for Citigroup. Now there’s an idea: maybe Santander

should buy Citigroup! If anybody’s capable of running an enormous international

bank, it’s Emilio Botín.

Posted in banking | Comments Off on Emilio Botin for Citigroup CEO!

You Just Can’t Find the Skilled Blue-Collar Workers These Days

When it comes to reasons for electricity prices going through the roof, the

inability of your local utility company to find qualified line technicians is

not going to be very high up the list. But when it comes to the US economy more

broadly, the inability of companies to hire good workers in unglamorous jobs

can be a serious impediment to economic growth. Andrew Leonard has a

great post on the subject:

In Florida, a line technician makes a base wage of $53,000 and with overtime

can earn up to $100,000. That’s pretty good money, for a job that can’t be

offshored and is unlikely to be nabbed by an illegal immigrant. But the electrical

industry is getting awfully nervous because, well, kids today don’t seem to

want to become line technicians, and the ones that are on the job are getting

a little gray around the temple. Half of Florida’s line technicians are reportedly

set to retire within five years…

There appears to be a perception that a job as line technician or welder or

pipe-fitter just isn’t considered "cool" anymore, regardless of

whether the wages are a hell of a lot more attractive than those offered by

your average fast food joint or coffee shop…

I found myself wondering what high school students in China or India would

make of the question of whether a job that can pay up to a hundred grand a

year is "cool" or "sick" enough to spur American young

adults out of a lifetime wallowing in anomie…

You have to wonder whether, in this case, there isn’t some truth to the theory

that there are some jobs that Americans just don’t want to do anymore.

The solution to the problem, of course, is very simple: immigration. There’s

a shortage of mathematically-skilled young people wanting to enter the Florida

blue-collar workforce? Not if you think globally there isn’t: I’m sure there

are hundreds of thousands of qualified individuals in India alone who would

jump at the opportunity. But those aren’t the kind of jobs you can get an H1-B

visa for.

Posted in immigration, labor | Comments Off on You Just Can’t Find the Skilled Blue-Collar Workers These Days

Replica Spam and the Poetry of Karl Marx

Never mind that Murakami

boutique at the Museum of Contemporary Art in LA. You only have nine more

days to buy a REPL1CA [W4TCH] from the Untitled

Project Store, which goes dark on November 18. Regularly priced at $850,

it can be yours for only $765! It’s a beautiful painted three-dimensional object

which, as the artist says, "is designed to occupy the physical and economic

space of a REAL replica luxury watch!"

Naturally, the store is being promoted by replica spam. Today’s is particularly

apropos, I think, given what’s going on in the commodity markets:

But, to avoid anticipating,

we will content ourselves here

with one more example relating to the commodity-form

itself. If commodities could speak, they would say this: our

use-value

may interest men, but it does not belong to us as objects. Our own

intercourse as commodities

proves it. We relate to each other merely as

exchange-values.

Karl Marx, Capital, Volume 1, Section 4

All of this is a project of Conrad

Bakker, an artist who loves to play with the detritus of our today’s electronic

existance: spam, eBay postcards, and the like. Often, the price of his work

is the most important part of the work itself; the spam, of course, is free.

Sign up for it yourself by sending an email to list@untitledprojects.com.

Posted in art | Comments Off on Replica Spam and the Poetry of Karl Marx

Extra Credit, Friday Edition

Deregulated

thinking: "Deregulation could be causing higher [electricity] prices.

But I suspect it’s only one factor among many, and would look relatively

small if you could effectively control for many of the other factors."

Bending

Ears on Economics as ’08 Nears: Uchitelle on presidential economics

advisers.

Translating

Ben Bernanke

An Economist Goes to a

Bar: The economics of dating.

More

or Less Quiz Winter 2005: I got 13/15.

Economy

Woes: One Felix Salmon was Larry Mantle’s guest on Thursday’s edition of

AirTalk.

China

fact of the day: Europe still exports less to China than it does to Switzerland.

The

$150M Castle: For those days when your $50m townhouse and your $27m Fifth

Ave apartment just won’t cut it, why not sleep in your $150m triplex on E 77th?

Posted in remainders | Comments Off on Extra Credit, Friday Edition

Mystery Stock Update

On Monday I wondered

what stock could possibly have been worthless at the end of 2005, but worth

$14 million at the end of 2006. A very loyal reader (really: the name on the

comment is "averyloyalreader") pointed out that the Boston Globe version

of the story

talked about "the private company whose stock they sold," which might

or might not imply that the company was closely held and not publicly-traded.

If it was public stock which got sold, however, Eddy

Elfenbein has a "completely wild guess": Cambridge

Heart. It’s in the right geographical neck of the woods, and its stock skyrocketed

at the beginning of 2006. At the beginning of December 2005 it was trading at

just 25 cents a share, which could well qualify as "worthless". By

March 17 2006, the stock was at $3.75 a share, giving the company a market capitalization

of more than $240 million. One can certainly see how a large slug of stock could

have been sold for $13.9 million.

And it’s lucky that they sold the stock where they did, too. The stock closed

today at just $1.38.

Posted in stocks | Comments Off on Mystery Stock Update

Has Nassim Taleb Killed Black-Scholes?

Nassim Taleb and Espen Haug have

a paper out. Here’s the abstract:

Options traders use a pricing formula which they adapt by fudging and changing

the tails and skewness by varying one parameter, the standard deviation of

a Gaussian. Such formula is popularly called Black-Scholes-Merton owing to

an attributed eponymous discovery (though changing the standard deviation

parameter is in contradiction with it). However we have historical evidence

that 1) Black, Scholes and Merton did not invent any formula,

just found an argument to make a well known (and used) formula compatible

with the economics establishment, by removing the “risk” parameter

through dynamic hedging, 2) Option traders use (and evidently have used since

1902) the previous versions of the formula of Louis Bachelier and Edward O.

Thorp (that allow a broad choice of probability distributions) and removed

the risk parameter by using put-call parity. The Bachelier-Thorp approach

is more robust (among other things) to the high impact rare event. It

is time to stop calling the formula by the wrong name.

Over at BreakingViews (subscription required), Pablo Triana explains

what this means:

The Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) option pricing model won two of its authors

a Nobel Prize in economics. But a potentially revolutionary paper by Nassim

Taleb and Espen Haug has thrown the whole edifice into question…

BSM may be reduced to what Taleb and Haug deem a “marketing exercise”.

All that BSM did is re-derive an already existing formula by using new and

quite fragile theoretical arguments.

Even more dramatic and watersheddy, Taleb and Haug argue that actual option

prices on the open market may be simply the result of the interaction of supply

and demand, with no formula involved. That goes against BSM, which says demand

forces should play no role in pricing…

Why is all this relevant? There are at least two crucial consequences. First,

the whole role of quantitative finance is thrown into question…

The second implication of Taleb and Haug is that implied volatility, a ubiquitous

element of the markets, ceases to make sense. In fact, it would cease to exist…

Rather than being the “market´s expected future turbulence”

or the “market´s fear gauge”, as conventional wisdom would

hold, implied volatility would have proven itself to be nothing but make-believe.

A nonexistent ghost.

Now I’m not remotely educated enough in such matters to critically assess the

Haug-Taleb paper, or its interpretation by Triana. But I am looking forward

to a spirited debate.

(Via Kedrosky)

Posted in derivatives | Comments Off on Has Nassim Taleb Killed Black-Scholes?

The World’s Wost ETF

Greg

Newton has found an ETF with the ticker symbol DCR, the MacroShares Oil

Down fund. Its net asset value is $7.91 per share, but its price is $14.25 per

share: a premium of more than 80%. Yes, I know that there are good

reasons to believe that oil is overpriced. But there are no good reasons

to buy DCR at $14.25 a share in the hope that the oil price will go down and

the fund will go up in price. Hell, the fund could go up in value by 50%, and

the shares would still be overvalued at $14.25 apiece.

Interestingly, Newton says that DCR was invented by none other than Robert

Shiller, of Irrational Exuberance

fame. Shiller’s not a big one for taking other people’s advice, I don’t think,

but in case he is, Newton’s unambiguous:

The MacroShares are irretrievably broken. They have never performed as advertised.

They show no signs of ever working as advertised. They are a disgrace to the

ETF market, and have been, pretty much since they were introduced. Nice try.

Didn’t work. Now kill them.

Is that easy? How does one go about killing an ETF, once one has launched it?

(Via Abnormal

Returns)

Posted in investing | Comments Off on The World’s Wost ETF

WSJ Circulation: A Correction

I

was wrong about the WSJ’s circulation on Tuesday; I got confused by some

slightly misleading language in the New York Times. If and when WSJ.com goes

free, the newspaper will still have a huge circulation lead over all other US

newspapers bar USA Today. Here’s a chart I made, which should explain how things

really are:

The blue bar is total newspaper circulation, which is just over 2 million.

Of that, around 350,000 newspaper subscribers (the light blue part) also subscribe

to the website. (Interestingly, the vast bulk of newspaper subscribers do not

have access to the website.) The red bar is subscribers to the website who do

not take the newspaper.

If and when WSJ.com goes free, then, the red part of this chart will disappear.

But the people who presently subscribe to both the newspaper and

the website will still (one assumes) continue to subscribe to the newspaper,

which means that total newspaper circulation should stay more or less at the

2 million level.

To be sure, there will be some newspaper subscribers who decide that if all

the content of the newspaper is available online for free, there’s no point

in paying for the paper. So circulation is likely to fall a little. But not

enormously.

Posted in Media | Comments Off on WSJ Circulation: A Correction