World Bank Biofuels Report Finally Released

Three weeks ago, the Guardian’s Aditya Chakrabortty published "the biofuels report they didn’t want you to read": the research paper from the World Bank’s Don Mitchell saying that 75% of the rise in global food prices could be attributed to biofuels. He said at the time:

Prompted by the Guardian’s report, the Bank may now push the report out – although it may not be in quite this form. We’d rather you saw the original, which is why

we’re publishing it today, here.

Well, the report is now out (PDF here), and if anything it’s better and clearer than the version the Guardian got. Here’s the controversial bit:

The combination of higher energy prices and related increases in fertilizer prices

and transport costs, and dollar weakness caused food prices to rise by about 35-40

percentage points from January 2002 until June 2008. These factors explain 25-30

percent of the total price increase, and most of the remaining 70-75 percent increase in

food commodities prices was due to biofuels and the related consequences of low grain

stocks, large land use shifts, speculative activity and export bans.

And here’s how the original report phrased things:

The decline of the dollar has contributed perhaps 20 percent to the rise in food prices. Thus, the combination of higher energy prices and related increases in fertilizer prices, and dollar weakness caused food prices to rise by about 35

percent from January 2002 until February 2008 and the remainder of the 140 percent actual increase was probably due to biofuels and the related consequences of low grain

stocks, large land use shifts, speculative activity, and export bans.

I can’t say that I see any evidence of censorship here. After all, like all World Bank working papers, it carries the standard disclaimer:

The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the

authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and

Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank

or the governments they represent.

According to Chakrabortty, World Bank president Bob Zoellick tried to suppress publication of the report – something which, if true, probably only served to draw further attention to it. In any case, it’s now out, in its full technicolor 21-page glory, and people can make up their own minds as to how persuasive it is.

(HT: Jevons)

Posted in commodities, world bank | Comments Off on World Bank Biofuels Report Finally Released

The Mystery of Merrill’s Asset Reduction

Alea is as eagle-eyed as ever:

The most important and most ignored sentence in Merrill’s press release:

The sale will reduce Merrill Lynch’s risk-weighted assets by approximately $29 billion.

How is this possible? After all, last month the CDOs being sold were valued at $11.1 billion, and indeed "Merrill Lynch’s aggregate U.S. super senior ABS CDO long exposure" has been reduced by precisely that amount.

A CDO is not, in itself, a leveraged instrument: you can’t lose more than you invested in it. If you’re carrying a CDO on your books at $11.1 billion, there’s no way that CDO can be responsible for $29 billion in losses, since its value can’t fall below zero.

But there’s more: since Merrill is lending Lone Star $5 billion to buy the CDOs, and the loan is non-recourse to Lone Star itself, the maximum that Lone Star can lose is its equity investment of $1.7 billion. If the CDOs went to zero tomorrow, then Merrill would suffer a further $5 billion of losses, and that contingent exposure should appear on the bank’s balance sheet somewhere, as the risk associated with the loan to Loan Star.

Maybe that’s where the $29 billion number comes from? Up until the sale, Merrill owned the CDOs outright, and if the CDOs all performed then those assets would have more or less their face value of $30.6 billion. Merrill took mark-to-model losses of $19.5 billion on those assets, but it still owned them, and kept them on its balance sheet under risk-weighted assets, valued at face.

Now, however, the CDOs have now been moved off Merrill’s balance sheet, and Lone Star gets all of the upside (minus the interest it’s paying on its $5 billion loan, of course). The $1.6 billion difference between $30.6 billion and $29 billion would then be Merrill’s risk-weighted exposure to the final $5 billion of possible losses: after all, the $5 billion loan to Lone Star is surely now a Merrill Lynch risk-weighted asset of some description.

Let’s say that Merrill considered the CDOs to be $30.6 billion of risk-weighted assets before the sale, and $0 afterwards. Then risk-weighted assets will have fallen from $30.6 billion in CDOs, to $5 billion in loans to Lone Star: a drop of $25.6 billion, not $29 billion.

So the only way I can see that Merrill could have got to $29 billion would be by risk-weighting the loan to Lone Star at just 32%: the $5 billion loan, once risk-weighted, would be counted as entailing risk of just $1.6 billion.

But even that doesn’t make sense. Before the sale, Merrill would have been counting 100% of the CDO assets as risk assets; after the sale, Merrill would be determining that $3.4 billion of the assets are essentially risk-free. It seems to me there’s some kind of weird remarking going on; if anybody could help me out, I’d be much obliged.

Oh, and one other thing from the press release: there was some commentary yesterday saying that the sold-off CDOs were mostly of 2005-and-older vintage. That’s not true: it’s Merrill’s remaining $8.8 billion of CDO exposure which is the older stuff.

Posted in banking, bonds and loans | Comments Off on The Mystery of Merrill’s Asset Reduction

The Economics of Checked Baggage

What to make of Delta’s new sliding scale for checking bags? On domestic flights, the first bag is free, the second is $50, and the third is $125.

This kind of thing is the exact opposite of most retail economics, where the more you buy the cheaper the unit cost becomes. Delta seems to think there are diseconomies of scale to checking bags: that checking twice as many will cost it much more than twice as much.

This is not intuitive. If you break down Delta’s baggage-handling costs into fixed and variable, the fixed costs would include the maintenance of the infrastructure and the wages of the baggage handlers. Maybe a drop-off in checked bags will allow the number of baggage-handling staff to come down a little, but I doubt those numbers would be very large. The variable costs, by contrast, are pretty much entirely a function of the bags’ weight.

Under its new scheme, one large, heavy bag travels free, while three small, light bags will cost you $175 and four will set you back $300. I’d love to be a luggage shop in the Delta departures area right now, selling big cheap duffels to passengers faced with sticker shock.

The obvious alternative would have been for Delta to charge by weight: give everybody an allowance of say 30 pounds, and then charge per pound above that. That would be fairer, and easier to understand too: right now the system is a complete mess, with international travellers paying $150 for three bags, but all of that being for the third bag, with the second flying free. And of course there’s a long list of exceptions: first-class passengers, elite frequent fliers, military customers.

Delta has twin motivations here: it wants to turn checked baggage into a profit center, while alienating as few paying customers as possible. Looked at from that point of view, its actions make a bit more sense: most people will pay relatively modest sums, while the big fees will be levied on travelers using the airline as a means of transporting luggage as much as themselves.

Even so, I suspect that most passengers would still be happier with a charge-by-weight system calibrated to generate the same amount of revenue. Big heavy bags are the bane of both travellers and baggage handlers: it’s not smart to incentivize their use in this manner.

Update: Joe Brancatelli emails with a good point: if airlines charged by weight, people would suddenly start developing a big interest in the accuracy of the scales at check-in counters — which, anecdotally, are not very accurate at all. "If airlines go to a by-weight system, local weight and measures bureaus will have be involved and that will require a whole new series of rules for the scales at the airport," he writes.

Posted in economics, travel | Comments Off on The Economics of Checked Baggage

Computers in the Oval Office

In England, they call it "silly season": the slow-news days of the summer where newspapers find themselves forced to run faux-provocative opinion pieces, just because there’s nothing else to fill the newshole. It was surely only a matter of time before someone at the WSJ decided to declare it a jolly good thing that John McCain can’t use a computer:

Does anyone who spends all day in front of a PC, forging a river of data posing as information, have any time to think?…

A computer, far from making you more productive, instead loads you down with things to do, and it’s important for the machine to know who is boss. Most people don’t have the luxury of off-loading their email-reading chores to a group of competent assistants. It’s an office perk that presidents are still important enough to deserve.

I suspect even the author of this piece, Lee Gomes, doesn’t really believe it. It simply can’t be better for a president to have all his information filtered through assistants playing office politics, rather than getting it directly from trusted sources who also have the advantage of not being paid employees.

Gomes claims it’s a better use of time for a president to have coffee with a blogger rather than to simply read that blogger’s thoughts online. But one can get much more information much more quickly by reading than one can through having coffee, even if the coffee is more enjoyable – although given the social skills of most bloggers, even that is far from a sure thing.

In any case, the president is the elected representative of the people, and the internet is the best way yet discovered for a president to keep in touch with his constituency. Does McCain’s computer illiteracy disqualify him from the presidency? No. But it is a severe handicap.

Posted in technology | Comments Off on Computers in the Oval Office

Bandwidth Datapoint of the Day

Tim Wu:

Americans today spend almost as much on bandwidth — the capacity to move information — as we do on energy. A family of four likely spends several hundred dollars a month on cellphones, cable television and Internet connections, which is about what we spend on gas and heating oil.

Wu blames this on a bandwidth cartel, which is largely fair. And he hints that the solution to the problem might lie in the fact that Americans also own vast amounts of hugely valuable, but largely unused, electromagnetic spectrum. Working out a safe and fair way of effectively utilizing that spectrum is a crucial priority which no one seems to care much about.

Posted in technology | Comments Off on Bandwidth Datapoint of the Day

Extra Credit, Tuesday Edition

Wine connoisseurs – I call them cons: The real lesson of the Judgment of Paris isn’t that California wines were better than French wines. It’s that wine tasters, when they’re really tasting blind, are clueless.

How Good Is The Mainstream Media At Linking Out? Not great, obvs, but yes the more you link out, the more links back in you get in return.

Emerging markets: hedge or diversifier? Great points from Abnormal Returns: It makes sense to diversify, even when correlations go to 1.

From Good to Great … to Below Average Management books are nearly all dreadful.

Paying too much attention to the price of gasoline

A Modest Proposal: Eco-Friendly Stimulus: Alan Blinder proposes federal "Cash for Clunkers".

And finally, Antony Currie needs a shave.

Posted in remainders | Comments Off on Extra Credit, Tuesday Edition

The Curious Case of Hernan Arbizu, Part 4

Hernan Arbizu (see entries passim, parts 1, 2, 3) has been arrested in Argentina! He’s charged with embezzling about $5.4 million from bank clients. Martha Graybow reports:

He was arrested on Monday in Buenos Aires and is being held by Argentine authorities, pending extradition, the U.S. Attorney’s Office in Manhattan said…

According to the criminal indictment, Arbizu initiated or helped initiate 12 unauthorized wire transfers from private banking clients at JPMorgan and UBS between March 2007 and April 2008.

This is a much bigger deal than we were given to understand until now. For one thing, how on earth did a JP Morgan private banker get access to UBS’s private-banking accounts? Is there some kind of law that UBS has to be involved in every banking scandal in America? And how come JP Morgan didn’t discover Arbizu’s embezzlement for over a year?

JP Morgan is seeking the return of the $5.4 million, which implies that Arbizu stole the money himself, rather than simply transferring it from one client to another, as originally seemed to be the case. Maybe that’s why the Argentines have decided to allow extradition proceedings to go ahead, despite the fact that Arbizu is an Argentine cititzen.

If this case does end up going to trial in the US, it should make for some pretty interesting courtroom theater. Given today’s developments, I’m hopeful that it will. But the one thing we know from the story so far is that when it comes to Hernan Arbizu, very little makes sense, and nothing ever quite goes according to plan.

Posted in fraud | Comments Off on The Curious Case of Hernan Arbizu, Part 4

When Banks Hide Fees in FX Rates

I just transferred some money from my US bank account to a vendor in the UK. Citibank’s wire-transfer fee was a modest flat rate of $20 — or so I thought until I looked at the exchange rate, which was fixed today, for wires under $10,000, at

2.0613 US dollars per British pound. Or, to put it another way, 3.5% above the actual exchange rate of 1.9916. In other words, the Citi fee isn’t $20, it’s $20 plus 3.5%. They just hide the 3.5% in the exchange rate.

Do banks do this for credit-card transactions too? If you buy something abroad do they charge the currency-conversion fee as well as making money on the FX conversion? And how is one meant to judge bank fees when they’re hidden like this and the exchange rate isn’t revealed until you’re all but done with the transaction?

Posted in banking, foreign exchange | Comments Off on When Banks Hide Fees in FX Rates

John Hempton, Financial Blogger Extraordinaire

In mid-May, Australian fund manager John Hempton started a blog which is already one of the best in the world for serious analysis of finance investment ideas on both the long and the short side. Coming back from holiday today I found a wealth of amazing blog entries there. Here’s just a taster of what Hempton’s done in the past couple of weeks:

Go subscribe/bookmark him now: you won’t regret it. And good luck, John, with suing Dell!

Posted in banking, economics, investing | Comments Off on John Hempton, Financial Blogger Extraordinaire

Hirst at Sotheby’s

A pair of unembeddable YouTube videos appeared quietly last Friday, and have made not much of a splash: Damien Hirst Beautiful Inside My Head Forever 1 and

Damien Hirst Beautiful Inside My Head Forever 2 have been viewed less than 400 times between them. But they were the first hints of the marketing campaign for a £65 million, 223-lot Sotheby’s auction of new Hirst works which is scheduled to be held in London over two days in mid-September. Maev Kennedy’s article on the sale comes with a slideshow of some of the works; the press release has more pictures still, but of course it’s the estimated prices which are the center of attention: zebra in formaldehyde,

£2 million to £3 million. Shark in formaldehyde,

£4 million to £6 million.

Calf in formaldehyde, complete with solid-gold hoofs,

£8 million to £12 million.

The press coverage of the sale concentrates on Hirst’s disintermediation tactics: by cutting out his gallerists, Jay Jopling and Larry Gagosian, he’s maximizing his own personal take from the sale. But I suspect that Jopling and Gagosian will still be bidding on behalf of clients, and otherwise intimately involved; in any case, Hirst and his business manager Frank Dunphy, rather than Hirst’s galleries, have been the people most in control of the market in Hirst’s work for some years now.

The real risk here is not that Hirst will alienate his gallerists. Nor is 223 lots so big relative to the size of the existing Hirst market that the sale risks flooding the world with too many works and bringing down prices. Rather, if all goes according to plan, Hirst’s prices will only rise as a result of this sale: an unknown number of hitherto unknown bidders, the kind of people who balk at negotiating with galleries about waiting lists and the like, will turn up because they reckon they have a good chance of walking away with something. Low estimates start at £15,000, and Sotheby’s will probably sell an enormous number of catalogues at between £65 and £80 apiece; these in themselves are likely to be marketed as collector’s items.

Sotheby’s is also compressing the time schedule dramatically: the catalogues are only being sent out at the end of August, just a couple of weeks before the auction. It’s all very feverish, and one can be sure that the sale itself will be mobbed with paparazzi and celebrities. I’m not entirely clear on how genuine bidders will even be able to be sure of getting in, but I’m sure they’ll find a way somehow.

My prediction is that the lower-priced works will exceed their estimates quite comfortably. A large colored-pencil dot drawing, for instance, is estimated at £30,000 to £40,000, and will surely sell for more. Meanwhile, a significant number of works incorporating diamonds will help to set a base level for the famous skull, if and when the consortium which owns it ever decides to sell. And almost certainly the total for the sale constitute the largest sum of money ever spent on the work of one artist at one time. It will make headlines, which will only drive Hirst’s values up ever higher.

Could it all go horribly wrong? Well, yes, anything can go wrong. But I suspect this particular sale won’t. The art bubble will surely burst at some point, but I don’t think the Hirst single-artist sale will mark the inflection point.

Posted in art | Comments Off on Hirst at Sotheby’s

Do Covered Bonds Have a Government Guarantee?

Steve Waldman reckons he’s worked out what the problem is with covered bonds:

A covered bond offered by Citi or Bank of America would only default if a titan collapsed. Investors might reasonably believe that would not be permitted to happen. If they are right, then these bonds are indeed covered. They are covered by you, dear taxpayer…

Covered bonds issued by "too big to fail" banks are basically equivalent to mortgage backed securities guaranteed by Fannie and Freddie. It’s just another way of putting private-sector bells and whistles on a public sector assumption of risk.

This is all true, but it’s not quite as bad as it might look. For one thing, the moral-hazard play on bank debt exists whether there are covered bonds or not. If Bear Stearns creditors were paid off in full one can reasonably assume that the creditors of Citi and BofA will be bailed out in extremis as well. So the extra risk borne by the taxpayer when these banks start issuing covered bonds is simply the extra risk put on these banks’ viability by the issuance of covered bonds.

And as it happens, covered bonds tend to be very safe things. What’s more, because they’re collateralized, a bank failure doesn’t necessarily imply that there’s going to be a taxpayer-financed bailout of covered bonds as well as senior unsecured debt, since the bondholders should be able to rely on their collateral.

The introduction of covered bonds is unlikely to massively increase banks’ balance sheets — not least because the banks’ regulators won’t allow it to. So the size of the implicit government guarantee on the debt of too-big-to-fail banks probably won’t go up all that much, at least for the time being. Meanwhile, the banks will have access to lower-cost funding, making it that much less likely they’ll fail in the first place. And we’ll slowly move away from the unhealthy system where substantially all new mortgages are bought by Fannie and Freddie, who now have a more-explicit-than-ever government guarantee.

A move towards covered bonds is hardly a panacea, of course. But I don’t think that it increases public-sector risk as much as Steve thinks it does. At the moment, mortgages are all-but-explicitly guaranteed by the federal government, because Fannie and Freddie are the only game in town. If covered bonds take off, then the implicit guarantee on too-big-to-fail banks is weaker than it is on Fannie and Freddie, and it also kicks in only after those banks’ equity cushions are wiped out. And remember that banks are much more strongly capitalized than Fannie and Freddie are. Plus, of course, the collateralization would have to fail as well.

Are covered bonds risk-free from a taxpayer perspective? Ultimately, nothing is. But I’m not losing sleep over any new risks here.

Posted in bonds and loans, housing | Comments Off on Do Covered Bonds Have a Government Guarantee?

House Prices: Bad, but Abating

Wow, those house prices are looking dreadful, aren’t they. Check out the headline on the front page of nytimes.com: "Home Price Index Down 15.8% in May" is the story. And the official press release from Case-Shiller is also very alarming: "Record Low Annual Declines Recorded in May 2008 for the

S&P/Case-Shiller Composite Home Price Indices" says the headline, above a chart showing house prices falling off a cliff.

Except, house prices didn’t fall 15.8% in May, they fell 0.9% in May, to a level 15.8% lower than they were a year previously. If you look at the actual level of the Case-Shiller, it fell to 168.54 from 170.00 – a decline of 1.46, which is actually the smallest month-on-month decline since August 2007. Back in February, the index fell by 4.75 points in one month, a much larger drop.

The index is based off a level of 100 in January 2000; it reached a high of 206.52 in July 2006. Its current level means that house prices are back to where they were in mid-2004.

Suppose some miracle happened and house prices nationwide rose by 10% in June. The index would go back up to 185.39, compared to a level of 199.44 in June 2007. Yet using today’s methodology, the headline on nytimes.com would say that the home price index fell 7% in June.

There’s no doubt that the housing market is in bad shape: according to the Case-Shiller index, house prices are now 18.4% below their mid-2006 peak. If you think that housing prices generally are going to fall 20% from the peak, we’re nearly there; if you think they’re going to fall much more than that, worse is yet to come. But certainly the rate of house-price declines seems to be abating a little.

All of which is why the focus on the year-on-year figures is silly. Look at the month-on-month figures to see what’s going on now, and look at the percentage-off-highs for the big picture. The 12-month decline is of interest only to people who bought a year ago and are selling now, which is a tiny fraction of the population indeed.

Posted in housing | Comments Off on House Prices: Bad, but Abating

Chart of the Day: Merrill’s Write-Downs

A picture tells a thousand words:

merrwritedown.jpg

Remember this. Just because a write-down is large, doesn’t mean it’s final.

(HT: Ritholtz)

Posted in banking | Comments Off on Chart of the Day: Merrill’s Write-Downs

Adventures in Technical Analysis, McClellan Oscillator Edition

When I dumped on technical analysis last month, one of the more unexpected results was a long email thread with a chap called Jeff Drake, on the subject of something called the McClellan Oscillator. He’s a big fan, while I was far from convinced. So we worked out a deal, pitching Jeff’s oscillator against my random results.

Jeff would let me know when the Oscillator next hit 60 (don’t ask), and compare his own three-day return from shorting the market to the three-day return I would have made shorting the market on a random date: the first of that month. He’d even spot me 50 points.

Last Thursday I got an email from Jeff, saying that the Oscillator gave a sell signal:

You sold the market on your random day of July 1 and closed 3 days later down 190 points (hmm….you’re pretty good at this) and then we’ll add 50 points for a total gain of 240 points. I’m selling the market today at 11,632 and we’ll see where we stand at the close next Monday.

Where did the Dow close Monday? 11,131: a drop of 500 points. Clearly, Jeff did a lot better with his carefully-timed technical analysis than I did throwing a dart at the calendar. And he’s quite evangelical about it, too:

I hope you finally realize that I’ve given you quite possibly the most financially valuable gift you’ll ever receive in your lifetime. Use it wisely and with strong discipline and you will easily and consistently beat the best annual return on investment that most long-term investors like Buffett and Lynch have ever gotten in their entire careers (and that’s with your portfolio sitting in cash 90% of the time).

I should note that this wasn’t a one-off thing: according to Jeff, the Oscillator has given buy/sell signals so far this year on February 1, March 3, March 10, June 12, June 24, July 15, and July 24. In most cases, buying/selling the broad stock market and then unwinding the trade after three days would have been very profitable; the June cases, not so much.

After all this, I decided that at the very least I should bother to find out what this Oscillator actually is. Investopedia came to the rescue, kinda:

To calculate subtract a 39 day EMA (of advancing issues – declining issues) from a 19 day EMA (of advancing issues – declining issues).

An EMA is an "exponentially weighted moving average," which means that more recent days are weighted higher than older days.

The main thing which strikes me here is how arbitrary all the numbers are. Why 39 days and 19 days? Why are the key levels on the oscillator +60 and -60? Why is the amount of time to hold the trade 3 days? These aren’t the kind of things which can be worked out ex ante: they’re used because they’re the numbers which have worked in the past. And, for all I know, they’ll work in the future as well. On the other hand, all trades work until they don’t, and nothing works forever.

The reason I’ll never trade on the McClellan Oscillator is simple: I don’t trade. (I’m a fan of the dictum that you should never enter any position you wouldn’t be happy holding for three years.) But, even if I did trade, I would never trade anything I don’t understand. And the McClellan Oscillator, with its emphasis on the difference between two pretty similar moving averages, is not something I can come close to understanding.

Could it be that there are some genuine reasons related to market psychology why the McClellan Oscillator has worked in the past? Well, possibly. But psychology is hardly an exact science either. And the idea that you can start with some kind of psychological tenets and end up with the difference between a 39-day moving average and a 19-day moving average – that’s surely impossible.

So I’m glad that Jeff is making lots of money trading his oscillator. But even he admits that he stayed short in June when the oscillator gave a buy signal, "because I follow a LOT of technical charts and I suspected the bounce would reverse quickly because the other charts were still very bearish".

Me, I’m much happier not following any technical charts. It’s much less confusing that way.

Posted in charts, investing, stocks | 1 Comment

The Failure of John Thain

Want proof that CEOs are overpaid? Just look at the mind-bogglingly awful Merrill Lynch announcement yesterday. It’s hard to know where to start: maybe the fact that Merrill is selling off $30.6 billion of CDOs to Lone Star for just $6.7 billion, of which $5 billion is Merrill’s own money. If there are any losses over and above the $1.7 billion difference, Merrill takes them, not Lone Star. Or maybe it’s the fat that Merrill valued those CDOs at $11.1 billion as of June 30. Or maybe it’s the fact that Merrill is effectively raising new money from Temasek at less than $7 a share, once you net out payments from Merrill to Temasek.

In any case, what’s utterly clear is that John Thain has lost all his credibility.

Remember January’s conference call? Thain was on top form: the worst was over, there wouldn’t be any more capital raising, assets wouldn’t be sold, and there couldn’t be any more CDO writedowns, since Merrill was putting on $23 billion of short positions against the CDOs exposures it retained.

All of Thain’s promises in January – all of them – have been broken. If it had been Stan O’Neal making the same promises, he would be the world’s biggest laughing-stock at this point; as it is, it seems he left just in time. When Thain took over, Merrill was trading at $58 a share; now it’s less than half that level.

Clearly what’s going on here is bigger than any CEO. Thain didn’t dither and make incomprehensible pronouncements; he was bold and clear about what he was doing and why he was doing it. But it didn’t help. And now even he has been reduced to the status of a jargon-spewing robot:

“The sale of the substantial majority of our CDO positions represents a significant milestone in our risk reduction efforts,” said John A. Thain, Chairman and CEO of Merrill Lynch. “Our consistent focus has been to opportunistically reduce risk, and in order to take advantage of this sizeable sale on an accelerated basis, we have decided to further enhance our capital position by issuing common stock. The actions we announced both today and on July 17 will materially enhance the company’s capital position and financial flexibility going forward.”

Don’t bother trying to find meaning in that prose, there isn’t any. As Roger Eherenberg points out, Merrill’s still being decidedly opaque on what kind of exposures it’s retaining. Over the past six months, Thain has gone from visionary to embattled and defensive, and at this point he’s no better than anybody else.

Or, to put it another way, CEOs don’t matter: if the company is going down the toilet, neither John Thain nor anybody else is going to prevent it from doing so. You could have put a monkey in charge, and the outcome wouldn’t have been materially different.

Posted in banking | Comments Off on The Failure of John Thain

The Economic Paradoxes of Contemporary Art

Don Thompson has written, by far, the best book on the economics of the contemporary art market yet written. It might seem like a narrow area, not enough to get a book out of – yet after wolfing down these 250 or so pages, I was left with a feeling that he’d barely scratched the surface.

There’s a lot in this book to fascinate someone new to the field, and as its title (The $12 Million Stuffed Shark) hints, there’s a lot of novice-friendly gawping at the artists who are best at generating tabloid headlines. Thompson disarmingly says at the beginning that he’s not going to discuss video installations, photography, and the like "because I don’t understand them", and he’s perfectly happy taking populist anyone-could-do-that pot-shots at major names like Jean-Michel Basquiat and Felix Gonzales-Torres.

Even so, this book is not only for the general public; I, for one, learned a lot from it, and a lot of art-world people would do likewise.

For instance, I had no idea that when a big-name artist has a gallery show at a big-name gallery like White Cube or Gagosian, his best paintings aren’t even on public view:

The new buyer has little chance of even seeing the hot paintings, which will be kept in a small private room. What is hung in public areas is available for purchase but of lesser significance.

Thompson also quotes Diana (Dede) Brooks, the former president of Sotheby’s, explaining that when an auction house has put a guarantee on an entire collection, rather than just one individual work, the reserve prices on those works can change during the course of the auction. This apparently happened with the $135 million sale of the collection of Campbell’s Soup heir John Dorrance Jr, on which Sotheby’s had placed a $100 million guarantee:

When some of the early Dorrance lots sold above estimate, Sotheby’s was able to decrease the reserves on those remaining. Had each item in the Dorrance collection been given an individual reserve, some lots would have been bought-in, and there would have been a loss of credibility about the other estimates.

Sadly Thompson leaves it at that: he doesn’t mention who is responsible for calculating these rapdily-fluctuating reserve prices, or how they are communicated to the auctioneer, who presumably has quite enough on his plate already.

But maybe such things really are left to the auctioneer’s discretion: in the heat of an auction, lines in the sand which one might suppose were hard to cross turn out to be surprisingly fluid. For instance, consider the case where a gallerist bids for a painting on behalf of a client:

Prominent New York art dealer Richard Feigen says that he often exceeds clients’ limits when bidding for them — whether it is a museum or an individual. "My job is not to be a robot but to use my knowledge and instincts for my client." Feigen says that in forty-seven years only one client has objected to his exceeding their limit.

Thompson puts this down to the dealer getting "caught up in the bidding". He’s excellent on the socioeconomics of the auction room, and the way they conspire to drive up prices: it’s not uncommon to see an editioned or otherwise fungible work sell for substantially more money than the asking price at a gallery down the street from the auction house. Part of that is the simple feverishness of the occasion, with billions of dollars being bid in an extremely compressed time schedule. And part of it is simple ego: an "auction house specialist" is quoted as saying that "Heaven is two Russian oligarchs bidding against each other". (I suspect that it was exactly that dynamic which resulted in the $11 million Goncharova.) On top of that, there’s the endowment effect, whereby people will pay more to keep hold of something they have than they will pay to buy something they don’t have:

Each bidder starts with a top price in mind. When he momentarily becomes the high bidder, there is an "endowment effect." He will pay more not to give up the painting, not to lose. Amid the tension of the auction, his reference point has changed to "I should win, this painting should be mine." He is aware of the regret he would feel at losing what has become "his".

Yet even so, some of the seemingly crazy bidding at auction can have a rational basis; at the very least, it can be rationalized. Art valuation is an extremely inexact science, and auction results are its most important datapoints: when you want to value a painting, you start by looking at the auction results for similar works, and one nearly always works on the assumption that they are realistic rather than the result of frenzied overbidding. If an insecure art lover wants a certain work and buys from a gallery, he’ll always have the worry that he was ripped off. On the other hand, if he buys at auction, he’s setting the value of the work: by definition, he can’t pay more than the work is worth. (In the art market, it seems, no one is particularly worried about the winner’s curse.)

And consider the position of the client who has given Richard Feigen or Larry Gagosian permission to bid on their behalf up to a certain limit, which is then breached. The client still wants the painting, and can buy it straight from the dealer "at cost", plus a modest commission. If he doesn’t, the painting will immediately enter the dealer’s inventory and will carry a much higher price tag. Besides, not only can dealers be very persuasive, but even the mere invocation of their name can cause hard-nosed businessmen to buy art they’ve never even seen:

Other shows at Gagosian sell out because a gallery employee phones clients and says "Larry says you need this for your collection." One former Gagosian employee claims that in about a quarter of the cases, clients say "I’ll take it" without ever asking "What does it look like?," or "How much?"

PaceWildenstein director Marc Glimcher has a wonderful name for this phenomenon:

"Larry has a special talent; clients don’t expect to see him, they are happy just getting the aura of Larry."

Just imagine the "aura of Larry" attached to a painting won at a major evening auction by Larry’s own paddle!

Thompson is excellent on the enormous influence that things like provenance or marketing or "aura of Larry" can have on the value of a work of art; he has a whole chapter titled "Branding and Insecurity" which makes a reasonably compelling case that dollar values in the contemporary art world are largely a function of marketing and branding rather than aesthetic judgment.

Yet at the same time Thompson does over-simplify. For instance, here he is writing about a Gonzales-Torres sculpture of 10,000 fortune cookies, offered for sale at Christie’s in 2003:

There was concern about how easily a collector might fake a 355 pound Gonzales-Torres sculpture with a visit to the local store. To deal with this problem, a note in the auction sales catalogue read: "It is the artist’s intention that a new certificate of authenticity and ownership is issued stating the new owner’s name, in addition to the current certificate of authenticity which accompanies this work."

In reality, the certificate of authenticity has very little to do with the ease of faking the work. The buyer isn’t buying the fortune cookies themselves but rather ownership of the work: the moral right to recreate the sculpture made from them and exhibit it as a genuine Gonzales-Torres, and the ability to resell the sculpture at a future date. When you buy a Gonzales-Torres, you buy the (largely conceptual) art, not the stuff it’s made from.

Disappointingly, Thompson seems a little too happy skitting along the surface of this central paradox of art economics: that while (most of the time) it is an object which is bought and sold, the dollar value lies in the art, not the object. If a painting formerly attributed to Rembrandt turns out to be executed by a minor follower, the object doesn’t change but its value plunges. It’s no different with a pile of candy: whether or not it’s a genuine Gonzales-Torres makes an enormous difference to its value. Thompson is happy conjuring up an art collector’s friends "staring open-mouthed and gasping: ‘You paid what for the candy?’", but he never points out that they might as well ask the same question about an object made of oil paint on canvas which would be equally worthless without the requisite author-ity.

And while Thompson is strong on the economics of art megastars Damien Hirst and Jeff Koons, he spends much less time and space on the economics of the other 99.9% of the art world. "The value of the canvas and oil that goes into a painting would not exceed £50," he writes, going wrong by an order of magnitude and inadvertently revealing that he’s probably never set foot in an art-supply store in his life. And while he thanks a long list of "dealers, auction house specialists, other art world people, and former executives from each group" who talked to him for the book, not one name on his list is an actual artist.

Partly as a result, there are a lot of omissions in the book. We get few concrete numbers when it comes to income: what’s the typical annual turnover of a mainstream gallery? Do such galleries make real money by selling new paintings, or are those shows loss-leaders for more profitable secondary-market dealing? What kind of money does a gallerist make overall? How much might a successful mid-career artist make from art alone? What different sources of income do such artists have? How do those numbers compare to the equivalent datapoints for superstar young guns? How long can those young guns expect their luck to last? Should they cash in today, maybe by consigning their work directly to auction houses, if they think that there’s a good chance their careers will be nowhere tomorrow? How does ancillary work like directing music videos compare, in terms of income, to the primary work of artistic production? And how do the more institutional and academic artists fit in to all this, people like Pierre Huyghe or Lothar Baumgarten, who seem to be much better at selling installations to institutions than selling objects to individuals?

One of the things which fascinates me about the recent run-up in contemporary art prices is that it’s meant a huge change in the way that many artists work: it’s commonplace nowadays for artists to have dozens of assistants, something which was a decidedly unusual and controversial practice back in the days of Warhol. With prices for new works regularly breaking into seven figures, art has become bigger and more polished; it often uses much more expensive materials and can draw on resources which would have been unthinkable 15 years ago.

And the base case for an artwork’s value has also changed so dramatically that options now exist for artists which would not have been possible in the past. Consider this: when Charles Saatchi bought the infamous Hirst shark for £50,000 in 1991, writes Thompson,

Hirst intended the figure to be an "outrageous" price, set as much for the publicity it would attract as for the monetary return.

Yet in Thompson’s final chapter, on "contemporary art as an investment", he has this advice for those who would invest in contemporary art:

Look for work costing from $50,000 to $100,000. Avoid the blockbuster, highest-priced works by an artist, not just because of the "underperformance of masterpieces," but to diversify risk, the same way you purchase a portfolio of shares rather than investing everything in one company. An investor is almost always better off with ten works at $50,000 by developing artists rather than a single work costing half a million.

How did we get from a world where £50,000 was an outrageously high price for a major work by a high-profile young star to a world where $100,000 is a relatively modest sum to be spent on an average work by a "developing artist"? I’m sure that improvements in art-branding technology had something to do with it, as did the scarcity of significant works from before 1945. But equally it does seem to be the case that we’re in the middle of a massive art bubble, and that there’s a real risk that in a decade’s time you won’t be able to sell your $500,000 ten-painting portfolio for even $50,000.

For that matter, it’s non-trivial even to dispose of such a portfolio today, at the height of the market. Thompson talks a lot about consigning work to auction houses, but they’re not generally particularly interested in $50,000 works from developing artists, and won’t put much marketing muscle behind such works even if they are accepted. Yet Thompson blithely gives this advice:

Plot prices as best you can, and when the steep rise ends and the flat phase seems to be starting, sell.

How do you sell? Do you try to unload your paintings back onto the dealer you bought them from? What are the chances of that working? If you had to sell that $50,000 painting the day after you bought it, what’s a reasonable sum that you might expect to be able to receive? (To put it in automobile terms, how much of a painting’s value is lost when it’s driven off the lot?) If you had to mark your $500,000 portfolio to market, in terms of its liquidation value, what’s the base value that you’re working from?

And what of the alternatives? In a world where $100,000 buys you a not-amazing painting by a developing artist, there are many. That same $100,000 can be used directly, as patronage: as price inflation for paintings continues to rise, the economics of disintermediating the dealer makes a lot of sense for both artists and collectors. Here’s Thompson:

For a mainstream gallery, and for an oil painting on canvas by an artist with no gallery history, £3,000 to £6,000 ($5,400 to $10,800) is about right. This is high enough to convey the status of the gallery and not cast doubt on the work or the artist, but low enough that, if the work is promising, it will sell.

If the first show sells out quickly, the dealer will say the pricing was correct. The artist may be underwhelmed, because even selling out one show a year at new-artist prices means she is still living below the poverty line.

Below the poverty line? If you sell a dozen paintings at $8,000 apiece, and the gallery takes half, that leaves you with an annual income of $48,000. The poverty line, by contrast, is $10,400.

But to give you an idea of the inflation going on here, check out the great Dave Hickey, writing in 1997:

When I was an art dealer, any biggish work of art was worth five hundred dollars. Any littlish work of art was worth two hundred. Today, a biggish work is worth a thousand dollars and a littlish work is worth three hundred.

Now, it seems, a biggish work is worth $10,000 and a littlish work is worth $5,000. This changes things for both artists and collectors enormously. For one thing, that new artist really can live on the proceeds of her work, where there’s no way she would have been able to do so ten years ago.

More to the point, an investor with $50,000 to spend on one artist has a choice: she can either buy a middling work from a middling artist at a middling dealer, or she can directly support an artist outside the gallery system entirely, buying pieces as necessary, maybe giving her a couple of thousand dollars to live on now and then, possibly helping out with studio space, that sort of thing. That kind of relationship is generally far more rewarding for the benefactor, and might well enable the artist to stay outside the gallery system for long enough that she has the time to develop a real artistic voice before being thrust blinking into the art-world spotlight. For the collector, the non-financial returns are much higher, while the financial returns can be equally large: what’s not to like?

Back in the days when the cost of a middling work from a middling artist at a middling dealer was an order of magnitude lower than it is today, this kind of math didn’t make much sense: it was much more expensive to support an artist directly than it was to simply buy their work at retail. But now things have changed, and serious artists who want to concentrate on their work more than they want to become the next branded megastar can support themselves by selling directly to a handful of devoted collectors, who might well consider themselves to be getting work on the cheap.

On the other hand, maybe the potential rewards of the gallery system are so huge, for artists, that a patronage model doesn’t make sense after all. Art-world gossip has a huge number of artists you’ve never heard of bringing home seven-figure incomes; a New York magazine profile of Terence Koh had him making $153,782 from his art when he was just starting out in 2004, and well over a million in 2006. Today, it’s surely greater still.

And if you can easily edition your art, the potential rewards are even bigger. Take Brazilian artist Assume Vivid Astro Focus: design a bunch of wallpaper once, and then sell it off by the sheet or the wall or the room as many times as you can. No collector seems to mind that their artwork isn’t unique: another central paradox of the art market is that prices rise as supply increases. The most prolific artists, like Picasso or Warhol or Hirst, sell for the highest prices, even when they have very little personal involvement with the art in question, while painters painstakingly creating unique objects sell for much less.

I think this is partly a function of the insecurity which Thompson talks about: collectors are happy paying millions of dollars for an artwork if they know that there are lots of other collectors who have also paid millions of dollars for something more or less identical. But it’s still a bit weird that someone like Jeff Koons can probably fetch more money per sculpture if he makes his works in editions of three rather than editions of one.

This paradox is also, however, a function of the art market being broken.

Thompson quotes Hickey too:

Dave Hickey recounts the story of his friend Bob Shapazian, who was director of the Gagosian Gallery in Los Angeles, and quit, according to Hickey, because: "I’m not an art dealer any more. I sit around, a crate comes in, I see who the crate’s from, I go to the waiting list, I make up this outrageous fucking number and send it out. That’s not being an art dealer."

This kind of thing is simply not sustainable. Yes, as Tyler Cowen says, "we do in fact need some means of determining which of the rich people are the cool ones, and the art market surely serves that end". But the art maket happily served that end at much lower prices than we’re seeing now, and it will continue to serve that end if and when prices again collapse.

In the meantime, if you’re a fan of today’s neoconceptual art, but there’s no way you can afford it, take heart: it’s pretty easy to make your own "Damien Hirst" spot painting, or "Noble and Webster" dollar sign, or "Lawrence Weiner" wall stencil. It won’t be worth anything financially, but aesthetically it’ll be functionally identical. It’s yet another paradox of contemporary art: owning it is ridiculously expensive. But simply having it on display? That can be incredibly cheap.

Posted in art, economics | Comments Off on The Economic Paradoxes of Contemporary Art

Ben Stein Watch: July 27, 2008

Ben Stein has some news for you, this week. "The economy isn’t at its best," he concedes. "But over all, it’s not all that bad."

Yes, little Benjy Sunshine is back, and he’s up to the same old tricks, especially when it comes to massaging the employment numbers: Dean Baker, as ever, does a great job of debunking his claims on that front. But he lets Stein get away with his misrepresentation of what recessions are:

It’s possible that the G.D.P. will not show growth in the second quarter. So, by the old definition — two straight downward quarters of G.D.P. — we cannot know if we have just entered a recession. We’ll get to the new definition in a moment…

Now, it is entirely possible that the National Bureau of Economic Research, the arbiter of recessions, will declare a recession. The bureau now uses its own judgment to decide if there is one. It bases its view on data on employment, industrial production, personal income growth, manufacturing, wholesale and retail sales, and a non-governmental estimate of the past quarter’s G.D.P. movement from a group called Macroeconomic Advisers.

Is there really no way that a Stein column can ever be fact-checked? Stein’s claiming here that there was an old way of defining a recession – two successive quarters of negative growth – which has now been supplanted by the new way, which involves the NBER using "its own judgment".

This is utter crap. The NBER has always been the arbiter of recessions, and it has always used its own judgment in deciding when they started and ended. No one with any authority ever claimed that there was a recession if and only if there were two successive quarters of negative growth; and as Lakshman Achuthan and Anirvan Banerji explain, such claims are dangerous. Not that Stein cares about such things, although his father certainly would have.

Stein is also far off base when it comes to the importance of the banking system to the economy:

Huge bank write-downs are bitter pills for the affected banks’ stockholders, but not enough to sink an economy of this size.

Ben, it’s not the write-downs which sink an economy, it’s the deleveraging. If the banks stop lending because they’ve run out of money, yes, that’s easily enough to sink an economy of any size, no matter what happens to government spending. Fiscal stimulus is all well and good, but it can’t offset the vicious deleveraging cycle.

Of course, this wouldn’t be a Stein column without a vapid and annoying attempt to sum everything up:

What is the future? We will get through all of it. “This great nation will endure as it has endured,” to quote F.D.R. We will then go on to whatever the new problems will be (probably the same as the old problems) and the media will have to find something new to complain about. This is called life.

Does Stein know what he’s quoting here? It’s FDR’s first inauguaral address, dating from the depths of the recession in 1933. Here’s a taster:

Values have shrunken to fantastic levels; taxes have risen; our ability to pay has fallen; government of all kinds is faced by serious curtailment of income; the means of exchange are frozen in the currents of trade; the withered leaves of industrial enterprise lie on every side; farmers find no markets for their produce; the savings of many years in thousands of families are gone.

More important, a host of unemployed citizens face the grim problem of existence, and an equally great number toil with little return. Only a foolish optimist can deny the dark realities of the moment.

This is where Stein turns when he wants to assure us that things are "not all that bad". Well, things are undoubtedly better now than they were in 1933, but I reckon that’s setting the bar pretty low. As for the implication that any perceived weakness in the economy is simply the fault of whining by the media, I’d urge Stein to look once more at FDR’s address, and its emphasis on the importance of candor. He might learn something.

Posted in ben stein watch | Comments Off on Ben Stein Watch: July 27, 2008

Lush Life

Matty’s cell rang.

“Excuse me,” half turning away.

“Got a pen?” It was his ex.

“Yup.” Making no move to find one.

“Adirondack Trailways 4432, arriving Port Authority, four-fifteen tomorrow.”

“A.m. or p.m.?”

“Guess.”

“All right, whatever,” glancing at Billy. Then, “Hey, Lindsay, wait.” Matty lowered his voice, his head. “What’s he like to eat?”

“To eat? Whatever. He’s a kid, not a tropical fish.”

One of the great things about Richard Price’s novels, as opposed to his screenwriting for The Wire, is that you can read the dialogue slowly, savor it, if you’re so inclined.

I might read this one again, to do just that. But the first time through, I was too overwhelmed. Not by the strength of the plot, which, a bit like The Wire, is barely enough to fill the vast amount of space available. And not by the three-dimensionality of the characters, either: they’re all maybe a little too glib, Matty and Yolanda in the novel being rather too close to McNulty and Kima in the TV series; Keith McNally and Schiller’s being a bit too obvious a center for the novel if you’re going to be writing about the yuppifying Lower East Side.

No, for me it was the wealth of Lower East Side detail, everything specified down to the street corner: the number of blocks it takes to get from Broome and Pitt to Eldridge and Stanton, that kind of thing. When you’re a New Yorker, and someone specifies an intersection, you can’t help but bring up a mental image of that corner in your mind. And when you’ve lived on the Lower East Side for the best part of a decade, and you’ve seen all these corners hundreds of times, and the novel is set deep into the real-world geography to the point at which even I had difficulty at times distinguishing the fictional from the real, that alone can be enough to distract somewhat from the artistry of the prose.

In any case, go and read this book: if you don’t know the LES quite as intimately as I do, it might be even better. On the other hand, if you do, and especially if you’re any kind of a fan of The Wire, then it’s simply a must-read.

You wait years for a great literary detective novel to come along, and then two arrive at once: this one, and The Yiddish Policemen’s Union. I’ve read them both in the past couple of months, and there are some uncanny similarities between them. I’m not going to play favorites, but if you like your fiction noirish and realistic and dirty, go for Lush Life. If you like it a little more magical, read the Chabon. And if you like it both ways, read them both.

Posted in Not economics | Comments Off on Lush Life

Signing Off

Just in time to avoid the aftermath of the dreadful Merrill results, I’m off on holiday. (Although it’s worth noting that the shares "sinking" 9% in after-hours trade only brings them back to where they closed yesterday.)

There won’t be anything here for the next few days, since I’ll be out of internet range, but by the end of next week it’s conceivable. We’ll see. Don’t break anything while I’m gone!

Posted in Announcements | Comments Off on Signing Off

Extra Credit, Thursday Edition

Clinton Foundation Sets Up

Malaria-Drug Price Plan

Ashmore Group Surges After Assets Under Management Increase: To $37.5 billion.

Called to account: The profitability of UK checking accounts.

Appointments With Red Ink: Citi execs criticize Pandit’s "dull platitudes". Color me unsurprised.

What Is Wrong With Short-Selling? Dean Baker asks.

“No Atheists in Foxholes.” No Libertarians in Financial Crises.

Cheap Wine: How Steve Levitt learned there was no correlation between wine price and perceived quality.

Posted in remainders | Comments Off on Extra Credit, Thursday Edition

One Hand, One Million Dollars, No Falsifiability

Joe Nocera has a provocative parenthetical in his list of the best business non-fiction books:

“Liar’s Poker”, by Michael Lewis (even though I’ve since become convinced that the anecdote that gives the book its title never happened).

The title, and its accompanying anecdote, is half the book. (The other half is the phrase "big swinging dicks".) If it never happened, it bloody well should have.

Posted in gambling | Comments Off on One Hand, One Million Dollars, No Falsifiability

The Busch and the Marlin

David Kesmodel has the wonderful story of what happened when Anheuser-Busch’s then-CEO, August Busch III, went on an ill-fated marlin fishing trip with a group of Modelo executives in the early 1990s. Go read the whole thing, it’s great. But my favorite bit is this:

Busch III declined to be interviewed for this blog post.

On the other hand, maybe if he had accepted the interview request, the story wouldn’t have been a mere blog entry any more.

Posted in M&A | Comments Off on The Busch and the Marlin

The Unconvincing Rally in Financials

Financials are on a roll right now: the XLF index fund, which tracks the S&P financials index, traded as high as $20.89 this morning, exactly $4 or 23.6% higher than where it traded at the same time Tuesday morning. That kind of volatility bespeaks short covering to me, which means that the growlings from the SEC might be partly responsible for this latest uptick.

The problem is that short-covering rallies, by definition, have no conviction and often don’t last long. We’re in the middle of earnings season, which means volatility’s probably going to remain high in the short term. And anybody looking at this mini-rally and seeing cause for optimism is, I fear, being decidedly premature.

Posted in banking, stocks | Comments Off on The Unconvincing Rally in Financials

The Competitive Advantage of Stock Exchanges Without Parking Lots

The headline of the day, without a doubt, is at Bloomberg News:

Pakistani Investors Stone Karachi Exchange as Stocks Plunge

Yes, they really started throwing stones at the physical stock exchange.

In Karachi investors today broke windows, threw plant holders in the parking lot of the building, burned shareholder statements and at least one protester was injured, prompting intervention by police and the paramilitary.

‘Cos the best way to stop your stocks from falling is to throw plant holders in the stock exchange parking lot. That’s bound to work, that is.

But there are more constructive ideas, too:

"We demand that all stock prices be frozen at current levels," said Kauser Javed, who heads the Small Investors Association.

Which might prevent a margin call or two – but would also prevent those small investors from getting any of their money out of the stock market at all. I’d advise Mr Javed to be careful what he wishes for.

Oh, and all this is taking place in the context of a stock market which has risen 14-fold since 2001. Here’s the five-year chart:

karachi.jpg

Yes, the Karachi stock market is down to levels not seen since March 2007. If that’s enough to cause riots, just imagine what might happen if stocks fell all the way to merely twice their value in September 2004!

Posted in emerging markets, stocks | Comments Off on The Competitive Advantage of Stock Exchanges Without Parking Lots

Bloomberg Datapoint of the Day

Back in 1985, investment-banking powerhouse Merrill Lynch bought a 30% stake in Bloomberg LP for $30 million. A few years later, Bloomberg bought back a 10% stake for $200 million, leaving Merrill with 20% — which it’s now selling, again to Bloomberg, for $4.5 billion.

Because of its financial duress, Merrill sold its stake at a discount, these people said. John A. Thain, Merrill’s chief executive, valued the Bloomberg stake at $5 billion to $6 billion when he spoke at a conference last month.

Since there were no other bidders, and since this was a sale under duress, it’s reasonable to assume that the real value of the 20% stake is something over $5 billion, and is quite possibly more than $5.5 billion, especially now that it has been consolidated into the principal’s controlling 92% shareholding. If that’s the case, then Bloomberg is now worth more than Merrill, whose market cap is $27.5 billion.

What’s more, Merrill isn’t even getting $4.5 billion in cash: it needs to lend that money to Bloomberg first. According to the NYT, Merrill "is providing financing for the purchase": essentially it’s converted Bloomberg equity into Bloomberg debt. Still, I’m sure that under some accounting rule or other this has done wonders for Merrill’s balance sheet.

Posted in banking, Media | Comments Off on Bloomberg Datapoint of the Day