The Henry Kravis Monologues

Michael

Flaherty reveals today that "at some point in the last few weeks, bankers

say that Citigroup Chief Chuck Prince paid a visit to the office of Henry Kravis…

What exactly transpired between King Henry and Prince is anybody’s guess."

We do know that KKR is angling

to buy Citi’s written-down debts: something John

Carney calls "very possibly the best story ever". So here’s my

fantasy of what went down.

"Vanessa, could you get Chuck Prince for me, please? No, not on the phone,

in person. Yes, here in my office. I have a great view of Central Park, why

would I want to go to his office? He’s on the third floor, ferchrissakes!

Yes, I know he runs the biggest bank in the world, that’s why I want to see

him… What’s that? Tomorrow? No, tomorrow doesn’t work, I want to see him now

He says he can be here in half an hour? Well, OK, but… whaddya mean he’s stuck

in traffic? What is he, weak? Tell him to get out and walk! He could use the

exercise, I tell you…

Chuck! Good to see you. Have a seat… Yes, it’s a Rembrandt actually. But

listen, I don’t have long, I’ll get to the point. You’ve agreed to lend me a

very large amount of money, and… no, Chuck, you’ve agreed to lend

me that money, you can’t get out of it now. Don’t pull that face, Chuck, I’m

trying to be constructive here… Would you just let me finish? Yes, I know

that all those loans are worth a lot less than face value. That’s why I want

to buy them off you…

Yes, duh I want all the Blackstone loans as well. You think I don’t

want inside Schwarzman’s business models? No of course I don’t care

what crab-legs might say, that’s your problem… Shall we start with say $50

billion and go from there? At say 94 cents on the dollar? I’ll pay you $47 billion

for all those loans, you never need to worry about them again… no, you’re

right, I don’t actually have $47 billion, but – here’s the really clever

part – you’re going to lend it to me!

Charles, come back here. Come back. COME BACK. Good. Sit down. Have a glass

of wine. ’47 Latour, since you ask. Yes, I know that lending me all that money

was what caused this whole problem in the first place. But things have changed!

Think of your stock price! Work with me here, work with me… everyone’s selling

your shares because you’re sitting on all these loan losses. So you write off

a few billion, mark the loans to a bit lower than you’ll sell them to me, and

you’re a hero, the stock goes up, the Dow hits a record high, your board doesn’t

want to fire you any more… here, have some more wine…

Yes, you’ll still have loads of loan exposure to highly-levered private-equity

shops. Yes you’ll have to take billions of dollars in loan-loss charges. Yes

if those loans end up performing then I’ll keep all those billions for myself.

But I’m tellin’ ya, the stock market will love it! You’ll make millions on your

stock options! Sandy will start returning your phone calls again!

And – here’s the best bit – you don’t have any choice! Now

run along and do as I say. There’s a good boy."

Posted in banking, bonds and loans | Comments Off on The Henry Kravis Monologues

Worrying About Mortgage Servicers’ Fate

Mortgage servicing is hot. Goldman Sachs is looking at buying the C-Bass servicing

unit, and there are many other deals going through as well, such as Wilbur Ross

paying $435 million for the servicing business of American Home, and Carrington

Capital Management buying the servicing business of New Century Financial for

$184 million.

I have to say this worries me. Joe

Giannone explains that loan servicing is an attractive business to be in

during a housing bust:

Litton makes changes to mortgages that can help struggling borrowers pay

their debt, a business that would do well as delinquency rates rise.

Ideally, however, loan servicing isn’t a standalone business – certainly

not one which should be levered up by Wall Street and then bought with the intention

of selling it later at a large profit. If you simply have a lender and a borrower,

then often the servicing arm of the lender can be incredibly valuable to both

sides: a good loan servicer will find a way to keep the borrower in their house,

and maximize the value of the loan for the lender, which otherwise might have

to write it off or go through a painful, expensive, and protracted foreclosure

process.

What happens, however, when the servicer is a for-profit entity not connected

with the lender? Suddenly, there’s a conflict between saving money for the lender,

on the one hand, and making money for itself, on the other. A simple mortgage

renegotiation is not very lucrative, for a servicer; a fully-blown foreclosure,

on the other hand, provides much more in the way of opportunities to profit.

More generally, any savings from the negotiation now have to be split three

ways (between the lender, the borrower, and the servicer) rather than just two

ways (between the lender and the borrower).

In other words, if servicers get bought up by financial investors, that’s bad

news for borrowers. What’s needed now is more common sense in the mortgage world,

and less profit motive. But the banks and hedge funds who are buying up the

servicers have nothing but a profit motive – and I can’t say that I’ve

seen a great deal of common sense from them of late.

Posted in housing | Comments Off on Worrying About Mortgage Servicers’ Fate

Beware Copyright Statistics

Dean

Baker is unimpressed by studies showing vast losses to the US economy from

piracy of intellectual property. He picks on a Washington

Post article by Frank Ahrens, which quotes a study concluding that "intellectual

property piracy — theft of music, movies, video games and software — costs

the U.S. economy $58 billion per year and 350,000 lost jobs in the entertainment

industry and its supplying industries."

Baker doesn’t like the economics:

The article wrongly claims that these violations cost the economy money.

This is untrue on its face. The losses to the industry are gains to consumers,

and those who know economics would know immediately that the gains to consumers

vastly exceed the losses to the industry. Some economic analysis would be

useful in this article.

Baker’s right that the study, from the IPI,

makes no attempt to calculate the gains to consumers from IP piracy. But in

fact the study is worse than that, because it also makes no attempt to calculate

the gains to the entertainment industry from IP piracy.

The methodology of the study is simple. The researchers (the author of the

study is Stephen Siwek) take their best guess of how many CDs and DVDs are illegally

copied or downloaded each year. In the case of CDs, they reckon that 1.4 billion

copied CDs are sold, along with 20 billion illegal MP3 downloads. They then

assume that 65.7% of purchasers of counterfeit CDs would have bought the real

thing instead, had the counterfeit not been available, and that 10% of people

downloading songs illegally would have paid for their music at a legitimate

download site such as iTunes instead.

From these numbers they come to the conclusion the entertainment industry loses

$1.6 billion to fake CDs, and another $3.7 billion to illegal downloading. They

then add those numbers together, to get a total of $5.3 billion, and apply a

"multiplier" which allows them to reach the conclusion that the total

loss to the US economy is $12.5 billion per year.

At no point in the study is the idea considered that wider dissemination of

music might actually help the music industry at all: I’m almost surprised

that Siwek doesn’t calculate the number of people who might buy CDs but don’t

because they can hear music free on the radio instead. Music is naturally viral:

the more people who listen to any given artist, the more people who are likely

to go out and buy that artist’s music. And then, of course, there’s all the

extra revenue to the music industry from merchandise and concert tickets which

are sold to people who didn’t buy the CD but still became fans.

Now I’m not saying that any of these effects completely couteract the losses

due to piracy, because I have no idea whether they do or not. But these effects

do exist, and it might be intellectually honest to at least take a stab at estimating

their magnitude before coming to the conclusion that the US entertainment industry

"loses" tens of billions of dollars a year to piracy.

In fact, of course, one can simply look at the stock price of entertainment-industry

companies to see that the advent of piracy doesn’t seem to have done them a

vast amount of visible harm. That’s why they need to wheel out researchers such

as Siwek to try and demonstrate assertions which, as Baker quite rightly says,

are untrue on their face.

Posted in intellectual property | Comments Off on Beware Copyright Statistics

Money Market Datapoint of the Day

All that money has to go somewhere, right? I asked

in September what was going to happen to all the money which used to be in asset-backed

commercial paper and other short-dated asset-backed securities. It seems that

a significant chunk of it has ended up at The

Reserve, a money-market funds company. Justin

Fox reports:

Concerns about safety at other money funds have boosted Reserve, which saw

its assets rise $10 billion (to $76 billion) in just the past four weeks.

That’s a huge rise – more than 15% in less than a month – but it’s

not surprising in the context of a broader flight to quality, if The Reserve

indeed has been good at staying away from subprime.

Interestingly, Bruce Bent, the founder of The Reserve, says that subprime-backed

assets really aren’t that risky at all. He stayed away from them himself not

because they could fall in value, but because his investors might not like them:

A money fund could go into a subprime and it could take the top tranche from

a credit point of view and not have a risk of losing principal, but what they

do lose is the commitment to the soundness of the sleep of the investors.

With even bank

depositors losing money these days, soundness of sleep is a good business

to be in.

Posted in bonds and loans | Comments Off on Money Market Datapoint of the Day

How Banks Calculate Their Write-Downs

The WSJ has a fabulous "Heard on the Street" column

today, worrying about all these losses being announced by big universal banks:

Citi, UBS, Deutsche. Are they worried that the losses are so big they will damage

the banks’ franchise? No: the worry is rather that the banks might be overstating

their losses:

While there is no evidence to suggest the banks are doing anything wrong,

numerous academic studies show that discretionary valuations related to possible

losses, which are often based on estimates, are an area of financial statements

that has in the past been manipulated by executives to manage earnings.

Doubtless there is some of this going on: if you’re going to write off, say,

$2.5 billion, you might as well make it a round $3 billion (that seems to be

the standard write-off these days), thereby giving yourself a bit of cushion

against further losses and possibly a nice bit of extra upside with which to

pad future profits.

On the other hand, all of these numbers are by their very nature inexact at

best, and I’m sure that most shareholders would prefer, in the present environment,

that these banks err on the side of caution.

Of course, the banks have to maintain the fiction that all these numbers are

entirely objective and accurate to umpteen decimal places:

Deutsche Bank said it "continues to apply accounting and valuation principles

consistently with prior periods." A UBS spokesman said the bank’s markdowns

"are appropriate and follow established accounting principles and industry

standards." A Citigroup spokesman said the bank "has taken impairments

in the third quarter based on a rigorous process applying appropriate accounting

principles."

I somehow doubt that anybody outside these banks considers the quality

of their earnings reports to be particularly consistent or rigorous, so I’m

not entirely sure who the banks think they’re kidding. What would happen if

a bank decided to be honest, and simply said something like this?

"We have a lot of very hard-to-value securities on our books, we know

they’ve fallen in value, but we can’t say how far with any exactitude, so

we’re going to take a large $3 billion write-down which should be more than

enough to cover any losses associated with the debt portfolio."

I have a suspicion that the sun would still rise the following morning. Although

you can never be sure.

Posted in banking | Comments Off on How Banks Calculate Their Write-Downs

A Brief History of HSX

Ten years ago, I was working in an office on Wall Street with a small group

of writers called the Teenage Mutant New Media Turtles. Officially, we were

writing economic commentary for high net worth individuals to subscribe to on

the internet. Unofficially, we spent a large part of our day trading movies

on the Hollywood Stock Exchange. It was one of

the most addictive websites any of us had ever seen, and of course, being New

Yorkers, we all got very competitive. What’s more, because movies got listed

long before they were released, the site was great at building anticipation

about forthcoming flicks.

Fast forward to today, and Chris Masse of Midas Oracle has republished a great

piece by Trader Daily’s Robert LaFranco on the rise and fall of HSX.

One of the founders is now the CEO of LionsGate; the other is a movie producer

in Paris. HSX is still going as a website, having been snapped up for almost

nothing by Cantor Fitzgerald after burning through $40 million during the dot-com

bubble, but it never really got traction within Hollywood. Its predictions for

opening-weekend grosses are as good or better than anyone in Hollywood’s, but,

a decade after it was founded with the intention of becoming a real trading

site, it still hasn’t managed to clear all the regulatory hurdles needed

to allow people to trade real money. (Meanwhile, InTrade

experimented with its own section for opening-weekend grosses, but it failed

because you couldn’t trade the gross itself, only the question of whether it

would come over or under a certain point, which gave the market much less predictive

power.)

Sooner or later, it seems, Cantor will finally start monetizing HSX and will

get into the business of entertainment futures. But this is a cautionary tale

for anybody with a dream: good ideas alone are only the beginning. Even with

millions of dollars and a hugely popular website, dreams can and will often

end up failing.

Posted in prediction markets | Comments Off on A Brief History of HSX

Economic Paper of the Day: Buiter on the Baltics

Academics love to niggle over small differences. Willem Buiter is an academic,

and today’s

he’s writing on the difference between three very similar things, with respect

to the currencies in the Baltic states and other small European countries:

  • A currency board, where the local currency has a fixed exchange rate with

    the euro;

  • Outright euroisation; and
  • A weird kind of halfway-house, whereby the euro becomes joint legal tender

    with the existing currency, and eventually becomes the de facto (but,

    crucially, not de jure) currency of the country in question.

Buiter has managed to write over 7,300 words on this subject, and I have to

admit I’m having a lot of difficulty trying to think of any way to persuade

you, my gentle reader, to click over and read them all. But really, you should,

because his blog entry (really a polemical academic paper, complete with footnotes)

is a model of an engaged, involved, and utterly persuasive economic essay.

The big-picture conclusion is that the Eurocrats are stupid hypocrites, and

that it now behooves all Europeans to support the Baltic states in their quest

for currency stability. Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania can and should join the

euro today – and thereby avoid becoming "rudderless playthings of

the international capital markets" like New Zealand (or, I might add, Iceland).

And if Brussels and Frankfurt don’t want to play along – well, then, the

Baltics should just go ahead and do the next best thing unilaterally (or, ideally,

multilaterally, all at the same time, maybe with Bulgaria, too).

Being a small country with a small currency confers no benefits for anyone.

It made perfect sense for Montenegro to simply adopt the euro as sole legal

tender, and Montenegro is an economic basket-case in comparison to the Baltics.

(In the Americas, Panama, El Salvador, and Ecuador have all made the equivalent

decision, and there was nothing the US could do to stop them.) Yet the Baltics

are barred from adopting the euro by arcane bureaucratic hurdles which make

no logical or economic sense. Congratulations to Dr Buiter for putting their

case so clearly and compellingly.

Posted in economics | Comments Off on Economic Paper of the Day: Buiter on the Baltics

How to Improve Commerce Bank’s Income

DealBook

asks today whether Toronto-Dominion Bank is overpaying for Commerce Bank.

They’re both customer-serviced, says RBC analyst Gerard Cassidy, but they have

very different profit margins:

The difference, Mr. Cassidy told The Times, is that Toronto-Dominion, which

operates in a much less competitive market, pampers its customers at a much

lower cost. The Canadian bank, Mr. Cassidy calculates, spends about 50 cents

for every dollar it generates. That amount is 74 cents at Commerce.

It’s true that Commerce’s home base of New York and New Jersey is less competitive

than, say, Toronto. But I’m not entirely sure what Cassidy is talking about

when he refers to dollars "generated". If he means loan income, then

he’s not really talking about the cost of pampering customers, he’s talking

instead about ability to generate loans. Here’s what Murray wrote in the comments

to my last blog entry:

CBH is great at attracting depositors. But it’s terrible at putting those

assets to work: it hates lending – at 36% its loans to deposit ratio is among

the lowest (TD’s is 65%). So it put majority of deposits in a securities portfolio

that it’s been losing money on here and there for the last 2 years. Not clever.

In other words, if Commerce’s costs remain the same, but it increases its loan-to-deposit

ratio from 36% to 54%, then – presto – its cost-to-income ratio

will fall from 74% to Toronto-Dominion’s 50%. And if TD can loan out the same

proportion of Commerce’s deposits that it does at the rest of its banks, then

Commerce’s cost-to-income ratio would fall (assuming costs stay the same) all

the way to 41%.

Now, it’s certainly possible that there’s some deep connection between Commerce

Bank’s customer service, on the one hand, and the fact that it makes very few

loans, on the other. Maybe it’s good at being nice to its customers because

it owes its customers money, rather than the other way around.

But banks buy and sell loans to and from each other every day: if Commerce

didn’t want to lend money to its customers, it could just buy loans from the

bank next door instead, and let that bank have the bad customer relationship.

Loan-to-deposit ratios are easy to increase.

Posted in banking | Comments Off on How to Improve Commerce Bank’s Income

Blogonomics: The Valuation of TechCrunch

Sam Gustin slaps

down Henry Blodget today after Blodget suggested

that TechCrunch might be worth $100 million. That’s ridiculous, says Gustin:

"I know CNET, and TechCrunch is no CNET."

The whole conversation was sparked by Doug

McIntyre at 24/7 Wall St. The math is relatively simple: CNet is valued

at $1.2 billion; maybe TechCrunch is worth a twelfth of that?

Certainly, by blog standards, TechCrunch’s traffic

numbers are impressive: at least 1.5 million unique visitors per month,

over 4 million pageviews per month, along with some 575,000 RSS and email subscribers.

More to the point, if you want to reach the most influential individuals in

the technology community, those subscribers and uniques are exactly

the people you’re looking for.

TechCrunch seems to be doing pretty well in terms of selling ad inventory,

but I’m sure it could do much better with a large and dedicated corporate ad-sales

team dedicated to it. Meanwhile, CNet seems to be going absolutely

nowhere, and needs a shot in the arm.

But CNet’s numbers – it measures monthly pageviews in the billions,

not millions – dwarf TechCrunch’s. There’s a good chance that a CNetted

TechCrunch would go the way of a Googled Dodgeball: lost and forgotten as part

of a much larger company. Frankly, I doubt that CNet has the structure or ability

to get anything like $100 million of strategic value out of TechCrunch. And

in any case, CNet is a consumer site: there aren’t actually all that many synergies

with TechCrunch in the first place, either on the reader side or on the advertiser

side.

TechCrunch is a bit like Italian Vogue: hugely important and influential,

but not necessarily the kind of property where you want to see much more growth.

TechCrunch already reaches nearly everybody who matters, and the marginal extra

unique visitor is not going to be particularly valuable to advertisers, compared

with the readers who have been reading TechCrunch for ages.

But let’s generously say that TechCrunch can achieve 100 million pageviews

per year, from important and influential readers. And let’s say that on each

of those pages CNet would be able to sell on average four ad units at a $7 CPM.

That would mean revenue of just under $3 million a year. By the time you’ve

paid the writers and the salespeople and all the other expenses associated with

the site, there’s no way you can get a revenue stream which remotely justifies

a $100 million valuation.

So I’m with Sam on this one. Blogs can be very valuable, and a blog network

like Gawker Media, which got

162 million pageviews in August, would be worth a very large amount of money

if there were anybody rich and foolhardy enough to want to buy it. But the idea

that a single blog, even one of TechCrunch’s standing, might be worth $100 million?

That’s pushing it.

Update: Doug McIntyre defends

the $100 million valuation, saying that "Most analysis of the value

of TechCrunch is based on what a financial model says it is worth. But, that

is not an accurate way to make the evaluation. The real question is what someone

would pay." Basically, he’s saying that TechCrunch is a strategic

asset, rather than a financial asset. But my point is that, really, it isn’t,

or at least that it isn’t qua blog. It might however have much more

value as a conference company than as a blog.

Posted in blogonomics, Media, technology | Comments Off on Blogonomics: The Valuation of TechCrunch

Radiohead Roundup

Thom Yorke reckons

that the music industry has a "decaying business model," and so he

and his band, Radiohead, have decided to opt out of it. Go to their website,

and you can download their new album for whatever you feel like paying.

My view on this is that it makes a lot of sense: by cutting out all the middlemen,

from EMI to iTunes, Radiohead builds a stronger connection to their fans, as

well as an enormous amount of goodwill. And a few other people seem to have

an opinion on this too.

Count me in with this lot:

The

Economist says that Radiohead’s move "reveals a recognition of the

fact that recorded music is no longer an excludable good; those who wish to

get recorded music for free will be able to do so, no matter how hard record

labels try to shield their product behind a wall of technology. Once one understands

that, it becomes clear that all music purchases are essentially conducted on

the honour system."

Bob Lefsetz

says that "it’s not like Radiohead’s living in a different world. But they’re

playing by a different rule book. One that says the money flows from the music."

Lefsetz also

says that Radiohead isn’t a technology company, and should have gone with

iTunes or Amazon or someone else who’s good at fulfillment and whose servers

won’t crash.

Greg

Mankiw says that this is a form of tipping, and "we economists don’t

understand tipping".

And here’s lots more commentary:

Dani

Rodrik’s wife says that Radiohead has gone bonkers, but still paid over

$10 for the album. Which leads Dani Rodrik to conclude that Radiohead has not

gone bonkers.

Fred

Wilson says that band is actually behind the technology curve: "We’ve

had the technology to allow bands to bypass traditional and online distribution

for years."

Chris

Dillow notes that "Canadian singer Issa

has a choose how much to pay system, and finds that 94%

pay at or above the suggested price for a downloaded track. Such systems demonstrate

that social norms really work. People behave honestly even when they needn’t

– they obey the social norm of reciprocity. "

Meg

Marco predicts that Radiohead "will make a hilarious amount of money".

Kim

Bayley of the Entertainment Retailers Association sounds a bit panicked,

saying that "the ERA does not support the distribution of music from just

one source because it limits access for consumers".

Chris

Anderson uses the opportunity to plug his next book: "Regardless of

what the average consumer decides to pay, this is another example of a business

model enabled by FREE. They only way Radiohead can enter into this with no idea

of what people will pay is because they have a product whose marginal cost of

manufacturing and distribution is close to zero."

Steve

Levitt wants to analyze Radiohead’s data.

Geoffrey

Manne says Radiohead is getting more than just money: "Here’s

what else they get: An excellent mailing and e-mail list. To buy (or receive

gratis) the album from the website one must enter name, email (and no cheating,

since download codes are sent via email), address, cell phone number, etc. For

Radiohead, this is a valuable list, I imagine."

Tyler

Cowen says that "no this model won’t much change the music industry".

George

Borjas takes the model to its logical conclusion: "The band’s history

suggests that many people (misguided as their tastes might be) would rather

listen to something else. Even at a nominal cost of zero, many of these people

will still not want to hear Radiohead’s music. The time spent listening to Radiohead

has an opportunity cost, and Radiohead will have to lower the price even further–below

zero–in order to attract them. In other words, the band will have to pay listeners

for the right to invade their airspace."

And Robert

Cyran says that "early indications suggest that Radiohead’s loyal followers

are paying too much for the band’s seventh disc."

Posted in Media | Comments Off on Radiohead Roundup

The Better You Look, The More You See

It seems that Bret Easton Ellis was on

to something when he invented Patrick Bateman:

For men, every extra 10 minutes daily grooming increases their weekly wages

by 6 percent.

Interestingly, the effect is much smaller for women: there really isn’t

any need to spend lots of hours and dollars straightening your natural

black hair.

The full paper, by Jayoti Das and Stephen DeLoach, is here.

(Via Alea)

Posted in pay | Comments Off on The Better You Look, The More You See

Solving the Dim White Kids Mystery

Andrew Samwick is very smart, in an academic way. What he values is some combination

of analytical intelligence, imagination, open-mindedness, and insight. If you’re

looking for that combination, the academy is a good place to start, and graduate

programs are a much better place to find it than undergraduates. So it’s not

surprising that Samwick

found his PhD class at MIT to be smarter than his undergraduate class at

Harvard.

Samwick wonders, however, about those undergraduates who "failed to impress"

him. Were they given some kind of artificial leg up in the admissions process,

on the grounds of race or wealth? He says no, and I believe him, and he also

says that it’s a "mystery" why these kids "did not seem to have

the intellectual firepower to be at the nation’s most selective institution".

No it isn’t. The fact is that if you’re a 17-year-old applying to Harvard (or

anywhere else), it’s all but impossible to give the admissions officer a really

good idea of your intellectual firepower. You can demonstrate a certain amount

of academic success at the high-school level, but that’s not at all the same

thing, and can be a sign that you’re a hard and diligent worker as opposed to

a brilliant prodigy who never really needed to work at anything. And in any

case Harvard would not want to admit only brilliant prodigies, even if it were

able to identify them.

The meritocratic ideal which governs Harvard applies not only to narrowly-defined

academic ability. Many of the "dim white kids" who failed to impress

Samwick went on, I’m sure, to highly successful careers – and I wouldn’t

be at all surprised to learn that it is they, rather than the superstars, who

ended up donating the most money to the Harvard endowment.

Posted in education | Comments Off on Solving the Dim White Kids Mystery

The Advisability of Real Estate Lending

Where was Mike Milken when I needed

him? I’m a veritable milquetoast compared to him: my view is simply that

buying a home isn’t always a good idea, especially not when it costs

less than half as much to rent as it does to buy. Milken, on the other hand,

goes

further:

It will be "quite a while before we have a robust housing market again,"

Milken said in an interview today. "The idea that any loan against real

estate is a good loan has never been a rational thought."

The "basic assumption" that home prices will continually increase

is wrong, said Milken.

I don’t necessarily agree with Milken on the subject of real-estate loans:

in general, I think that a real-estate loan with good underwriting – that

is, a real-estate loan where the borrower can repay the mortgage out of his

income – is likely to perform reasonably well. Occasionally, it won’t:

ask any Japanese bank which lent money against commercial real estate in the

mid-80s. And, of course, there’s no shortage of real-estate loans which are

not well underwritten, both in the subprime sector and, more recently,

in commercial real estate. But those are artifacts of bubbles, and I think that

in the grand scheme of things, lending money against property is a good business

to be in. After all, your mortgage is pretty much the last thing you’re going

to default on.

Posted in bonds and loans, housing | Comments Off on The Advisability of Real Estate Lending

League Table of the Day

"It’s not my fault being the biggest and the strongest. I don’t even exercise."

–Fezzick (André the Giant), The Princess Bride

The top ten movies on iTunes,

with their year of release

Rank Title Year
1 The Princess Bride 1987
2 Wild Hogs 2007
3 Zoolander 2001
4 Unbreakable 2000
5 The Italian Job 2003
6 High School Musical 2006
7 Aeon Flux 2005
8 National Lampoon’s Van Wilder 2002
9 Failure to Launch 2007
10 Get Rich or Die Tryin’ 2005

Happy 20th anniversary, TPB!

Posted in Media | Comments Off on League Table of the Day

Location, Location, Location

JP Morgan’s Michael Feroli says, in the words

of the WSJ’s Real Time Economics blog, that all Fed politics is local. Which

Federal Reserve banks wanted a cut in the discount rate? The ones where housing

prices were looking weak. The Federal Reserve Banks with strong housing markets,

on the other hand, didn’t want a cut in the discount rate. Here’s David

Altig’s version of Feroli’s chart:

feroli_picture.jpg

It’s cute. But Altig isn’t impressed. He points out that "Federal

Reserve Bank districts are a bit larger than the cities in which they are based,"

and asks:

What do you suppose happens if I take Feroli’s chart and replace

Atlanta with Miami (the residents of which have exactly the same claim on

the attentions of the Atlanta Fed as those who live in Georgia)?

You can click

through to his blog entry if you don’t know the answer. And Altig has to

say that he treats Miami with exactly the same amount of attention as he treats

Atlanta: he is director

of research at the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, after all.

But I still suspect that Feroli might be on to something. After

all, if it was that easy to treat all parts of the country equally, there would

be no need to have separate Federal Reserve banks at all: everything could (and

probably should) be centralized in Washington. The idea, of course, with the

system as it stands is that if you’re located in a certain place you’ll be more

attuned to what’s going on there. And clearly, if you’re based in Atlanta you’re

naturally going to be more attuned to what’s going on in Atlanta than you will

be to what’s going on in Miami. You can try to keep everything econometric and

objective as much as possible, but as Alan Greenspan has been saying ad

nauseam of late, economics often comes from gut feelings, and you get gut

feelings not only from looking at numbers but also from overhearing conversations

about house prices.

Posted in fiscal and monetary policy, housing | Comments Off on Location, Location, Location

Paul Collier in New York

I went to a great talk by Paul Collier on Friday, at the Cooper Union. I blogged

his new

book, "The Bottom Billion," in June, and I was looking forward

to hearing him in person: after all, he comes impressively blurbed by the likes

of Ernesto Zedillo, Nick Stern, George Soros, Martin Wolf, Nick Kristof, and

Larry Summers. And boy are they right. Collier is no one’s idea of a charismatic

public speaker, but he’s utterly compelling, and I can easily believe that he

managed to persuade EU trade commissioner Peter Mandelson to change Europe’s

trade policy with Africa after a single meeting.

Collier’s main plea is for people to really educate themselves on the plight

of the world’s poorest. At the moment, there’s a huge amount of goodwill, but

precious little real knowledge – a situation which lends itself to gesture

politics, where it’s more important to be seen to be Doing Something than it

is to actually do the right thing.

Collier made a lot of excellent points in his short talk, and the talk only

covered a small part of the scope of his book. But it’s worth reprising a few

of the main themes.

  • Targeting global poverty sounds like a great idea, but global poverty is

    going to go down substantially no matter what, thanks to the economic development

    of China and India. It’s the "bottom billion" of the book’s title

    who are really falling behind, not the global poor more generally.

  • Aid is important, but if the rich really want to help, they need to make

    efforts on much, much more than just aid. (Collier’s other main areas where

    the rich can help are trade, security, and governance.) The problems of the

    bottom billion are often problems caused by civil war, or resource curses,

    or other problems which aid can’t solve.

  • A big-picture view has to replace the country-by-country approach which

    dominates now. Some 30% of Africa lives in resource-poor, landlocked countries

    (compared to just 1% of the world population), and those Africans are doomed

    unless the whole neighborhood improves. "The best interventions might

    not be in the countries themselves," says Collier: "the only hope

    for Niger is that Nigeria grows".

  • Details matter, a lot. The difference between the African

    Growth and Opportunity Act, in the US, and Everything

    but Arms, in Europe, comes down to pretty technical differences on things

    like country-of-origin rules. But it turns out that where AGOA has a waiver

    on country-of-origin restrictions, African exports to the US have gone up

    sevenfold; meanwhile, EbA, with no such waivers, has done no visible good

    at all.

"This is what you need to get up to speed on," exhorted Collier of

the studenty crowd. Slogans aren’t enough: what’s needed is pressure on politicians

to do very specific things like extend these trade-with-Africa acts to all of

Sub-Saharan Africa and not just to the poorest countries which don’t have the

institutions to make use of the opportunities afforded to them.

If you only read or recommend one book on development issues, this is the one.

Collier is a clear-headed realist who knows that if we don’t solve the problems

of Africa now, they will spill over into the developed world sooner rather than

later. He has solutions; the task now is to start enacting legislation.

Posted in development | Comments Off on Paul Collier in New York

Ag Prices: The Long Hemp, Short Corn Trade

A funny thing, government interference in markets. The US government, thanks

mainly to the fact that the Iowa caucus is politically very important, is doing

its best to encourage the market in corn ethanol. But front-page articles in

both the NYT

and the WSJ

have the price of ethanol plunging. Meanwhile, the Dutch goverment is cracking

down on the market in marijuana, and even George Michael is cutting

back on his intake, but the main visible effect is that marijuana

prices are up 20% this year. Maybe what the corn industry needs isn’t subsidies

but a few armed raids!

Posted in commodities | Comments Off on Ag Prices: The Long Hemp, Short Corn Trade

Adventures in Contextual Advertising

From Justin Fox’s Curious

Capitalist blog:

teaser.jpg

Posted in Media, technology | Comments Off on Adventures in Contextual Advertising

The NYT, the Dollar, and the Savings Rate

Back in August, the NYT editorial page displayed

its economic ignorance by blaming the weak dollar, inter alia,

on a low domestic savings rate. It got slapped

down by both Greg

Mankiw and Dean

Baker: a low savings rate causes a stronger dollar, and raising the domestic

savings rate would only serve to weaken the dollar further. D’oh!

Of course, we all make mistakes. But smart people learn from their mistakes,

especially when they get free advice from eminent economists pointing those

mistakes out. Which is why it’s rather depressing to see the NYT make exactly

the same mistake all over again this morning:

Dollar weakness is home-grown. It is rooted in the borrow-and-spend behavior

of the United States government and American consumers and in a corollary

lack of domestic savings that necessitates foreign borrowing.

Baker’s on

the case, again, of course. But if they didn’t listen last time, the NYT

ediorialists are unlikely to listen this time. The fact is that fiscal recklessness

of the sort displayed by the present administration is harmful in many different

ways – but the one thing you can’t blame on fiscal recklessness

is the weak dollar.

Posted in economics, foreign exchange | Comments Off on The NYT, the Dollar, and the Savings Rate

Commerce Bank: An Expensive Strategic Asset

The $8.5 billion acquisition

of Commerce Bancorp by Canada’s Toronto-Dominion Bank is being greeted with

something of a shrug this morning. When Commerce CEO Vernon Hill was ousted

in June, it seemed only a matter of time before the company was sold –

but analysts were expecting the franchise to get something between $45 and $50

per share, rather than the $42.37 at which this offer is valued.

There’s lots of talk

this morning about how greenbacks are cheap for Canadians these days, of course.

But Commerce’s assets are all in US dollars, and they’re clearly worth less

– in US dollars – now than they were before the liquidity crunch

of July and August.

So let it just be noted that TD is paying more than 2.8 times book value for

Commerce Bank, which is a very high multiple for a retail bank heading into

an economic downturn. The multiple comes not from enormous growth prospects:

if anything, Commerce’s home market around New York and New Jersey is overbanked.

Rather, it’s a function of the rapid consolidation of the US banking system.

Mid-sized banks are extremely attractive, these days, to big banks which are

finding it hard to grow organically and therefore feel that they need to grow

by acquisition. In other words, they’re strategic, not financial, assets –

and get priced accordingly.

So the price that TD is paying might not be much of a premium to where Commerce’s

shares have been trading. But those shares have been pricing in a possible acquisition

since June.

Posted in banking | Comments Off on Commerce Bank: An Expensive Strategic Asset

More on the NetBank Failure

Last night I talked to Chris Coulthrust (not Colthrust) of Applied Cognetics,

about the NetBank

implosion. Understandably, for someone who’s just lost access to what he

thought was money safely in the bank, he’s not a happy bunny. And equally understandably

he was a bit concerned about my blog entry, because it was long on the throwaway

snark and a bit short on facts.

So the first thing to clear up is that Coulthrust is not some kind of subprime

spiv who took his morally-dubious profits and put them in NetBank. He did work

at a subprime lender in the late 1990s, long before the subprime bubble, but

he was not a founder of the company, which went bust, and in fact he left that

job with substantial debts. After many years at various technology startups,

he eventually founded Applied

Cognetics, which does have one subprime-related product, but which is making

most of its revenues from other sources.

Coulthrust also helped me find all manner of interesting information on the

FDIC website. NetBank’s total deposits came to $2.3 billion, which is less than

its total assets of $2.5 billion. That should come as some reassurance to Coulthurst

and other uninsured depositors, although of course the assets are long-dated

and illiquid and might take some time to monetize.

The scope of

the uninsured-depositor problem is not huge: NetBank had approximately $109

million in 1,500 deposit accounts that exceeded the federal deposit insurance

limit. Of that $109 million, 50% is being paid out in an immediate payment by

the FDIC (exactly what "immediate" means in this case is not entirely

clear), leaving just under $55 million in unreachable deposits in total. The

FDIC is also spending $110 million of its own money, from the Deposit Insurance

Fund, to help keep most depositors whole, and of course ING is paying $14 million

of its own money in order to get NetBank’s deposits. So by the time

all’s said and done, the losses to NetBank depositors are likey to be small.

Should NetBank’s depositors, like Coulthrust, have suspected that something

nasty was going down? If they were paying close attention, then yes. NetBank’s

share price was in the pennies for most of this year, which meant that the equity

cushion protecting depositors was very small indeed, and their only real hope

was that NetBank would be acquired by EverBank. So when EverBank abandoned

the proposed acquisition on September 17, the gig was up.

But the fact is that with $100,000 of FDIC insurance, most Americans quite

reasonably don’t spend much time worrying about how safe their banks are. And

so it’s understandable that a small and fast-growing company like Applied Cognetics,

whose accounts had much less than $100,000 in them most of the time, might not

consider a large windfall in terms of revenues to be cause for concern.

And while financial-market professionals are comfortable thinking of bank deposits

as one type of banking-industry liability, most individuals don’t consider themselves

to be lending money to the bank when they make a deposit. Rather, they think

of themselves to be simply placing their money in the bank for safekeeping and

easy access. Applied Cognetics had $100,000 in a NetBank checking account which

paid zero interest.

Interestingly, the reason that Applied Cognetics had all of its money in NetBank

to begin with was basically due to the fact that Commerce Bank, in Brooklyn,

made it so difficult for Coulthrust to open a business account there that he

eventually gave up and decided to do everything online instead. He says he went

back to Commerce Bank four times, with all the different bits of paperwork they

were asking for, but that they were never satisfied, and seemed more interested

in asking none-too-intelligent questions about his business model instead. My

guess is that they were stealth-underwriting a loan he hadn’t even asked for,

although it’s also entirely possible that they were simply incompetent.

Finally, it’s probably just as well that the legendary Robin Kelton died in

April. Kelton was a financial-industry giant, who founded not only the investment

bank Fox-Pitt Kelton but also the rating agency IBCA (now part of Fitch), and

the insurance rating agency ISI (now part of S&P). Kelton was on the board

of NetBank from day one, and he would have been devastated to see its depositors

out of pocket.

Posted in banking | Comments Off on More on the NetBank Failure

Blogonomics: RSS Feeds

Have I mentioned that I take requests? Today Sandy leaves

a comment for me, asking me to explain the economics of RSS

feeds; I’m happy to oblige.

The comment keys off my description of FT.com’s decision to truncate its RSS

feeds as "idiotic". Why so, asks Sandy – aren’t blogs an ad-driven

medium? Don’t you need to visit a web page to see its ads? And doesn’t truncating

an RSS feed force people to visit the web page in order to read the whole thing?

The answers to those questions are yes, yes, and yes. But.

First, it is possible to put ads in RSS feeds, and no one I know objects to

them. Indeed, the future of ads in RSS feeds helps to explain why Google thought

that it was worth spending $100 million to buy Feedburner. But it is true that

at the moment, these ads are neither particularly sought-after by advertisers,

nor are they particularly clicked-on by readers. It’s fair to say that ads served

and viewed on a web page are more valuable than ads served and viewed in a feedreader.

Second, there are lots of reasons beyond ad revenue why people might want to

write and publish blogs. Fred

Wilson, for instance, makes money from his blog despite having no advertising

on it: instead, it helps him find investment opportunities. Most of the top

econobloggers are tenured professors who use their blogs basically as a high-level

economics seminar. And so forth. But yes, if you’re talking about blogs on the

likes of FT.com or Portfolio.com, I’m quite sure that the publishers are going

to want to see as much ad revenue as possible from all those pageviews.

So if web pageviews are worth more than RSS pageviews, and if a truncated feed

sends readers from the RSS feed to the web page, isn’t a truncated feed a no-brainer?

Not at all. In fact, there’s very good reason to believe that a full RSS feed

will end up driving much more traffic to the web page than a truncated

RSS feed will. Mike Masnick of Techdirt puts his finger on one part of the

reason why:

In our experience, full text feeds actually does lead to more page views.

Full text feeds makes the reading process much easier. It means it’s that

much more likely that someone reads the full piece and actually understands

what’s being said — which makes it much, much, much more likely that they’ll

then forward it on to someone else, or blog about it themselves, or post it

to Digg or Reddit or Slashdot or Fark or any other such thing — and that

generates more traffic and interest and page views from new readers, who we

hope subscribe to the RSS feed and become regular readers as well. The whole

idea is that by making it easier and easier for anyone to read and fully grasp

our content, the more likely they are to spread it via word of mouth, and

that tends to lead to much greater adoption than by limiting what we give

to our readers and begging them to come to our site if they want to read more

than a sentence or two.

And Robert

Scoble says something similar:

RSS lets people read about 10 times the amount of content than if you just

use a Web browser. That’s why journalists, connectors, bloggers, geeks

who care about productivity, etc use RSS. It’s also why advertising

in RSS isn’t yet working. These people aren’t good targets for

loosely-targetted advertising…

So, how does anyone make any money?

Well, let’s stay in TODAY’S world. In today’s world you

get journalists, geeks, bloggers, connectors, to read your content and link

to it. That’ll bring a larger audience to visit your Web page. How do

you do that? Serve out full-text RSS. Why? Cause by doing that you treat the

connector with the most possible respect and give him/her the easiest way

to consume your content and link to it.

It’s undeniable that RSS users love full feeds and hate partial feeds –

to the point at which we will tend to skip over the partial feeds even if we

don’t unsubscribe from them entirely. When Megan McArdle started blogging at

the Economist, I subscribed to her feed. When she left, the feed remained –

but I think I’ve actually clicked through and read the blog exactly once since

then under its new author, because the feed is so truncated as to be all but

useless.

More generally, I’ll skim through all manner of stuff in a feed reader that

I’d never read on a web page. Entries are just easier to read when they’re cleanly

presented in a black font of my choosing on a white background with no annoying

colors and graphical elements. So if you want me to read your stuff, serve up

a full feed. And you do want me to read your stuff, because if I do

then there’s a good chance I’ll link to you, and that will drive traffic your

way.

There are other reasons to serve full RSS, too. For one thing, most feedreaders

allow their users to browse content offline. I been known to catch up on quite

a lot of blogs while on a train or a plane. And you can’t do that with truncated

feeds.

What’s more, nearly all feed readers have a search function, and people use

their RSS readers to search for stories they’re interested in. Their search

term is much more likely to come up if you serve a full feed rather than a truncated

one. The FT should certainly know this, because they do it themselves. Here’s

a little something they published

back in April:

Which led blogger Felix Salmon to note that investment

banks are now primarily valued for their ability to bring their own risk appetite

to the table. “And they’re not just taking on senior debt, they’re

taking on equity bridges and even outright equity risk,” Salmon writes.

The URL they used to link to me is very, very long. It’s not a direct link

to my blog; it’s not even a link to Feedburner which redirects to my blog. Instead,

it’s a link they pulled off a blog search they did in Bloglines.com, searching

on the terms KKR and "investment bank". If I hadn’t been serving the

full version of my blog, my blog entry would never have come up in their search

results, and they wouldn’t have linked to me. But they did, and my website got

extra traffic – even though the FT themselves never actually visited

it.

So if you want to maximise your advertising revenues, you want to maximise

your traffic. And the way to do that is not to put up barriers which stop people

from reading you or finding your stuff. Rather, the best way to do that is to

get inbound links. And a full RSS feed will generate many more inbound links

than a truncated RSS feed will.

Amy Gahran

understands:

Partial feeds are popular with media organizations and others who measure

success primarily by counting pageviews on their sites. That is, they think

it’s more important to lure people to their site so they can count them and

increase their online ad rates, than it is to build loyalty by finding better

ways to serve online communities on their own terms.

Even if truncating RSS did increase pageviews, it would still be a

bad idea: as Jeff Jarvis says

ad nauseam, what publishers are really selling is their relationship

with their readers, more than easily-quantifiable eyeballs. And so they should

be trying to make that relationship as good as possible.

In any case, publishers should stop thinking of websites just as websites,

and start embracing all of the rest of the internet – not only HTML but

also XML and anything else that will bring their content to their readers.

But the real reason why truncating RSS feeds is idiotic is simply

that it’s stunningly self-defeating. I used to read Slate a lot; now, I don’t,

because I’ve moved from the web to RSS, and Slate hasn’t. Likewise, the FT’s

Alphaville blog. Hell, I’m even unlikely to notice Portfolio.com content, if

it doesn’t turn up in one of the RSS feeds, and one of the reasons why I’m sometimes

bad at responding to comments here is that I don’t have a comments feed to keep

me up to speed.

I’ll admit to being something of an outlier when it comes to RSS usage. But

we RSS outliers are precisely the people that the likes of FT.com want

to attract. They’ll work it out eventually, I’m sure.

Posted in blogonomics, economics, Media, technology | Comments Off on Blogonomics: RSS Feeds

Poetic Justice in NetBank Implosion

It hasn’t got a lot of headlines, but the US has now officially suffered its

biggest bank

failure since 1993. NetBank had $2.5 billion in assets, and somehow contrived

to lose more than $200 million in 2006. Deposits were insured up to the FDIC

ceiling of $100,000, and ING Direct is buying $1.5 billion in deposits for $14

million, which works out at about $1,000 $135 per new customer.

Of course, there’s always going to be someone with more than $100,000 in deposits.

But in

this case it’s hard to feel a huge amount of sympathy:

Applied Cognetics, a software development and online marketing firm based

in Brooklyn, N.Y., has about $1 million in deposits in NetBank…

NetBank customers with accounts exceeding the FDIC limit will become creditors

in NetBank’s receivership, the FDIC said Friday…

Applied Cognetics bills itself as a one-stop shop for online lead generation

and Internet development.

Colthrust and his team – who formed the company after a subprime mortgage

lender where they worked was sold – have built the 10-employee company’s sales

to more than $10 million since it was founded in 2000. Ironically, given that

lenders’ catering to subprime borrowers have led to a spike in home loan defaults,

subprime lead generation software is among the services Applied Cognetics

sells.

So Colthrust started a subprime lender, sold it, and then used the proceeds

to start a company finding leads for other subprime lenders. He also put all

his money in NetBank, which promptly went belly-up in the subprime meltdown.

There’s some kind of poetic justice there, I think.

Posted in banking | 1 Comment

Picking an Inflation Measure and Sticking With It

It’s the Inflation Wars! Barry

Ritholtz and Dan Gross

and John

Wasik and Johnny

Debacle and dozens of others are elbowing each other out of the way to proclaim

from the rooftops that we have a Serious Inflation Problem and that the Fed

should therefore raise rates – or, at the very least, not cut them. Brad

DeLong tries to fight against the tide, but he must be feeling a bit lonely

out there.

My feeling about all this is that it all depends on which measure of inflation

one chooses to target – and this is crucial – ex ante.

At any given point in time, something is inflating at a dangerous pace.

It might be tech stocks or houses or food prices or wages or hotel rooms or

bicycle tires, but the key to taking any given inflation hawk seriously is to

ask whether they were in any way reassured that inflation was not a

problem when their chosen indicator was not rising in price.

The Fed has said, quite consistently, that the measure of inflation it cares

about most is core inflation, as measured in nominal dollars, ex food and energy.

You can argue with that decision, but once they’ve made that decision, I’m not

a fan of suddenly deciding when food and energy prices rise that, oh deary me,

they do matter for monetary-policy purposes after all.

Personally, if I were going to ask the Fed to target anything, I’d be tempted

to ask them to target the TIPS spread on 10-year bonds. But my point is that

if the TIPS spread starts gapping out and the Fed isn’t targeting it,

then they really shouldn’t panic and start raising overnight interest rates

as a result. The Fed has enough on its plate trying to target just one measure

of inflation. Let’s not try and force them to target half a dozen.

Posted in fiscal and monetary policy | Comments Off on Picking an Inflation Measure and Sticking With It

Is Brad DeLong Turning on Alan Greenspan?

Now here’s an interesting development in the Greenspan

Wars. Brad DeLong, Greenspan’s apologist-in-chief, spends

884 words essentially saying "well, it’s not Greenspan’s fault he’s

a political hack". Since Paul Krugman’s chief complaint about Greenspan

is that he (Greenspan) turned out to be a political hack, it seems that DeLong

and Krugman might not be quite as far apart on this issue as we thought.

DeLong first says that Krugman is asking a lot of a man who is, after all,

a Republican, and then constructs this astonishing imaginary dialogue between

Greenspan and James Baker, in the run-up to Greenspan’s nomination as Fed chairman:

Greenspan: Paul Volcker is a very good guy, but he regards

himself as a technocrat. He is not political, like you and I are.

He does his technocratic job. Carter appointed him. Yet the fact that his

monetary policies cost Jimmy Carter reelection was simply not something that

entered Vocker’s mind…

Baker: Volcker says that he had no choice, that he had to

act in 1979-1980…

Greenspan: There is always a choice. It would be a shame

if it came around to 1991, and somebody who did not understand the political

realities like you and I do were sitting in the Fed chair. My old teacher

Arthur Burns always understood political realities…

Baker: You make some interesting points. I think I understand

you…

With friends like these, Greenspan hardly needs enemies: DeLong is essentially

admitting that Greenspan allowed party-political considerations to drive his

behavior during the Bush 43 administration. (Although he was either too principled

or too green to allow those considerations to drive his behavior during the

Bush 41 administration.)

For the record: yes, both DeLong and Krugman can reasonably be considered

to be political hacks are political partisans themselves. But as far

as I know, no one has ever proposed that either of them join the board of governors

of the Federal Reserve, let alone chair it. Economists are more than welcome

to be political hacks. Central bankers, no.

Posted in fiscal and monetary policy | Comments Off on Is Brad DeLong Turning on Alan Greenspan?