Did FASB Scupper the Auction-Rate Market?

Auction-rate securities certainly don’t look very much like cash equivalents these days, as the WSJ shows, citing retail investor Naveen Ahuja, who is unable to sell $665,000 of the things.

For investors like Mr. Ahuja, the unrest in a formerly sedate corner of the credit markets is hitting close to home. In recent years, auction-rate securities have been sold to finance everything from hospital expansions to student loans. Issuers liked them because they paid lower rates on an instrument that functioned much like long-term debt, which typically carries higher rates. Investors liked them because they got higher rates than other so-called cash equivalents, but they still could be liquidated quickly. It seemed a marriage made in heaven — until the market failed.

Clearly auction-rate securities aren’t "cash equivalents" any more, if they ever were. So the Financial Accounting Standards Board looks positively prescient for once: way back in March 2007, it announced that the heading "cash equivalents" should be eliminated from balance sheets and cash-flow statements. And a good thing too: investors don’t want to be poring over balance sheets, wondering whether thos "cash equivalents" are actually completely illiquid auction-rate securities.

On the other hand, John Carney today looks at all this another way, and basically says that it’s FASB’s fault the auction-rate securities are failing.

Corporations responded to [FASB] by moving out of the auction-rate securities so that their balance sheet cash positions would not take a hit. This meant that many corporations were no longer in the market for the securities. As corporate demand for auction-rate securities vanished, banks found themselves having to soak up more and more inventory. The capital commitment required to do this grew at the same time the banks faced challenges from other parts of the credit markets. Last week they decided that against committing additional capital to supporting the auction, and let them fail.

In a narrow sense, this is silly. The proximate cause for the failure of the auctions has nothing to do with FASB: it’s the fact that no one has any faith in monoline wraps any more. If the FASB decision had never been handed down, investors wanting lots of liquidity and zero credit risk would still have exited the auction-rate market en masse, just because they no longer trust the monolines.

On the other hand, the FASB decision hardly helped matters. Many of the corporate investors who left the market in the wake of the FASB decision might well have been perfectly happy with a little bit of credit risk. And if they had stayed, we probably wouldn’t have had as many auction failures as we’re seeing now.

Update: Mark Conner says in the comments that the change happened in 2005, not 2007; that it wasn’t driven by FASB and in any case hasn’t even taken official effect yet; and that, after a very brief pause back then, corporate demand for auction-rate securities actually increased in its wake.

Posted in accounting, bonds and loans | Comments Off on Did FASB Scupper the Auction-Rate Market?

Middle-Class Kids do Very Well at Bad Schools

Please let there be more research along these lines. Do kids who go to "good schools" (either schools in expensive school districts or private schools) do better, academically, than kids who go to underperforming schools in the inner city? Are you sure? Even after controlling for socio-economic status? I’m not at all sure, and now the Times is reporting on the most recent study in England with this headline: "Privileged children excel, even at low-performing comprehensives".

Now this is a small study, based on interviews: there isn’t lots of mathematics controlling for SES and that sort of thing. Hell, there isn’t even a direct comparison with results from independent schools. But the fact is that the middle-class kids the study is looking at – who went to underperforming schools largely because of their parents’ political views – really did do very well academically.

Interestingly, the one area where the kids didn’t do well was connected to the reason why they were sent to state schools in the first place: social integration.

Our research found segregation within schools with white middle-class children clustered in top sets, often benefiting from ‘Gifted and Talented’ schemes, with little interaction with children from other backgrounds.  The children rarely had working class friends and their few minority ethnic friends were predominantly from middle-class backgrounds.  There was much evidence of social mix but far less evidence of social mixing.

I’ve said for years now that school fees are probably the single most expensive thing that anybody ever spends money on without doing any kind of cost-benefit analysis or wondering whether it’s actually worth the price. There’s a feeling that such considerations are a sign of bad parenting, almost. But if you want your kid to get very good grades and hang out with other middle-class children, it seems you can get that result at much lower cost by sending her to the local state school.

This doesn’t mean that "good schools" are no better than "bad schools". The parents in the study generally were governors of the schools in question (they wanted to be involved) and the kids in the study generally got much more teacher attention than most kids, and wound up in those "Gifted and Talented" schemes. Middle-class kids get unfair advantages wherever they go, it seems. It’s just that middle-class parents seem to be loath to take advantage of that fact by sending their kids to the local state school.

But just think of the money saved by not sending your kid to a private school. And think what you could achieve if you spent that money on other forms of education – books, travel, music/dance lessons, private tutoring, whatever. For the ultra-wealthy who won’t even notice the school fees leaving their private-banking account, it probably doesn’t make much difference. For everybody else, however, the state-school option is very much worth considering.

And remember, as Chris Dillow says, if it doesn’t work out, you can always change your mind.

Posted in education | 7 Comments

Extra Credit, Thursday Edition

Incredible Correlation: Credit markets just get worse and worse.

Fear and loathing, and a hint of hope: The Economist surveys the world of securitization.

S&P cuts 28 CPDOs after revising ratings models

How Did KKR Financial Become A Buyout Loan SIV?

Posted in remainders | Comments Off on Extra Credit, Thursday Edition

State and Local Taxes Shouldn’t be Deductible

Back at the end of 2004, the New York Times warned darkly that the Bush Administration had plans up its sleeve to abolish the deductibility of state and local income taxes on federal tax returns. And lo, less than a year later, the President’s Advisory Panel on Federal Tax Refrom went ahead and recommended just that. But it never happened. Unfortunately. Maybe President Obama will be able to bite the bullet and make it happen.

Today the Congressional Budget Office released a 54-page report going into lots of detail about the implications of abolishing this deduction, which costs the federal government more than $50 billion per year. (The CBO director’s blog entry is here.) Some points to ponder:

  • Only about 35% of taxpayers opt to take this deduction, and they’re generally rich: more than 80% of the benefits of the deduction in 2004 went to people earning more than $75,000 per year, and 16% of the benefits went to people earning more than $1 million per year.
  • Eliminating the deduction would increase federal revenues by an estimated $748 billion during the 2008-2017 period.
  • Replacing the deduction with a 15 percent credit

    would increase federal revenues by $165 billion over

    those 10 years, and actually increase the after-tax income of people earning less than $75,000 per year.

I’ve never liked the mortgage-interest tax deduction either, but right now’s not the time to abolish it. The state-and-local-tax deduction, however, really makes no sense. Taxpayers should pay income tax on their income: that’s what the large majority of Americans do, and that’s what the rich minority should do too, if things are to be fair. Instead, more than 90% of people earning more than $100,000 per year get to lop off a sizeable chunk of their income and pay federal taxes only on the remainder.

What’s more, the deductibility of state and local taxes, along with the deductibility of mortgage interest, is a large part of the problem when it comes to the Alternative Minimum Tax. If you stop people taking silly deductions which shouldn’t exist, then you also obviate a large part of the need for the AMT.

It’s true that the impact of this move would be asymmetrical, with New Yorkers hit particularly hard. Well, so be it. New York is a blue state: it should be happy with a more progressive fiscal regime.

Posted in fiscal and monetary policy | Comments Off on State and Local Taxes Shouldn’t be Deductible

Chart of the Day: Jerome Kerviel’s P&L

kerviel.jpg

Alea has found this amazing chart, showing Jerome Kerviel’s real P&L at SocGen. The thing that fascinates me is that after a very bumpy ride indeed for most of the year, suddenly Kerviel’s profit remains uncharacteristically and astonishingly static for essentially all of December. Kerviel’s made his monster profit, and he’s simply sitting on it. By sheerest coincidence, the bank then offers him a bonus of €300,000. The minute he starts a new year, he’s off trading again, and immediately falls off a cliff. As Alea writes,

I am wondering why he should get a 300k bonus for a P&L officiel around 0.

Posted in charts | Comments Off on Chart of the Day: Jerome Kerviel’s P&L

Pimco: Even Bigger Than You Thought

Are you in the mood for 4,500 words on how Pimco is alleged to have illegally squeezed the Treasury market in 2005? Then run along to Bloomberg forthwith. The details of the lawsuit bore me, with the exception of the factoid that the whole thing sprang out of a Gretchen Morgenson column back in 2005. I’m more interested in Pimco’s sheer mindblowing size: it has $747 billion in assets. The article quotes pension consultant Michael Rosen:

Small or large, bond funds and money managers are trying to wring profit from shrinking fee levels, Rosen says.

"Fees have gotten very, very low,” he says.

Annual fees and expenses for U.S. bond funds fell 14.4 percent to 83 basis points, or 83 cents per $100 invested, in 2006 from 2001, according to the Washington-based trade group Investment Company Institute. The decline, which the group traces partly to increased competition, is more dramatic since 1980, when bond funds charged $2.05 per $100…

Why do Pimco and the others bother with funds management?

"It’s like the joke about the Jewish deli,” Rosen deadpans. “The food’s no good, but the portions are huge. You have to ask them why they want it. I don’t think they’re making a lot of money on it.’

Munich-based insurer Allianz SE, which bought 70 percent of Pimco in 2000 for $3.3 billion, won’t say how much money Pimco is making; it doesn’t break out results for the unit or its 37 funds.

Rosen doesn’t think they’re making a lot of money? Some simple math: if Pimco is making 83 basis points on $747 billion in assets, that works out at well over $6 billion in fees per year. Say Pimco has annual payroll expenses of $1 billion (it only had 824 employees as of last year) – that still leaves $5 billion to cover everything else. My feeling is that Allianz is extremely happy with its acquisition.

As for the allegations of Pimco being a bully, I heard many such allegations myself when I was covering the emerging-market bond market. There are advantages and disadvantages to being big: the disadvantages are that it’s very hard to be nimble or to get in or out of your positions, while the advantages are that you can often get what you want if you throw your weight around a little. It’s natural that Pimco would want to take advantage of its enormous size; the only question is whether it crossed any legal lines when it tried to do so.

Posted in bonds and loans | 2 Comments

When Economics is Relevant

David Leonhardt today applauds Esther Duflo and Abhijit Banerjee of the Poverty Action Lab at MIT for "making economics relevant again". His column is the result of his second annual survey of economists; the first came up with a list of 13 untenured "economists to watch".

Today is a good day to laud economists, since it is also the day that Jim Poterba has been named the new head of the NBER, replacing the universally-admired Marty Feldstein. Poterba’s appointment comes as no surprise, and is likely to go down well among economists. Congratulations to him, to Duflo and Banerjee and their colleagues, and to everybody else who is keeping economics relevant and interesting, both in the academy and in the blogosphere. It’s a rare and special skill.

(HT: DeLong)

Posted in economics | Comments Off on When Economics is Relevant

Investment-Banking Bullshit Watch, Global Coordinator Edition

Lauren Goldstein Crowe has a question:

J.P. Morgan Chase & Co. and Mediobanca will be the global coordinators on the Ferragamo IPO. UBS is the joint book-runner. And no, I don’t know what that means either.

The answer is that it means, essentially, nothing. Here’s the explanation from the Official Market Movers Banking Explainer (whom, I’m afraid, will have to remain anonymous):

"Global Coordinator" was a bullshit title dreamed up in the 1990s to make banks sound even more important. It basically was the same as joint bookrunner.

What I think it means now is that JPM and Mediobanca are the bookrunners, and UBS isn’t quite the bookrunner but hates the idea of being called a co-manager – as all but the smallest of IBs do.

It is, in other words, vacuous bullshit meant to assuage the pointlessly overinflated egos at the investment banks.

Clearer now?

Posted in banking | Comments Off on Investment-Banking Bullshit Watch, Global Coordinator Edition

Obama a Comfortable Favorite in Texas?

Over at InTrade, Hillary Clinton is tanking. Her chances of winning Ohio were 65% yesterday; that contract last traded at 47.5%. Meanwhile, her chances in Texas have plunged from 48% yesterday to just 30% now.

The last time we saw price movement like this, of course, it was in New Hampshire, where Clinton ended up winning. And I suspect there’s more noise than there is signal in today’s price movements. But the expectations game is clearly changing: a few days ago, winning Texas was a baseline scenario for Clinton. Now, winning it will give her positive momentum.

Posted in prediction markets | Comments Off on Obama a Comfortable Favorite in Texas?

Crocs: On the Down Escalator

Crocs, manufacturers of extraordinarily ugly popular shoes, released spectacular fourth-quarter earnings yesterday afternoon, with both revenue and earnings almost doubling their levels from a year previously. Obviously no one’s particularly worried about the escalator problem.

The stock, however, is down 13% today. Colin Barr thinks it’s because demand was so strong that the company had to ship some shoes by air freight; Kathy Shwiff thinks it’s because the 2008 earnings forecast fell short of expectations; and David Phillips thinks it’s because inventories rose a lot. Me, I just think that what goes up must come down.

Posted in stocks | Comments Off on Crocs: On the Down Escalator

Will Bond and CDS Prices Ever Converge?

If bond and stock prices are out of whack, then maybe it shouldn’t come as any surprise that bond and CDS prices are also trading miles apart from each other. In fact, you have to be careful when you try to take a measure of the difference between bond and stock prices, since many of the most-used indicators of the fixed-income market are actually indices of credit default swaps, not bonds themselves. And so really the disparity between bonds on the one side and stocks on the other is more of a disparity between the CDS market on the one side, stocks on the other, and bonds somewhere in the middle.

There are good technical reasons why the CDS market is trading wide, which are glossed today by Across the Curve. Structured products like the notorious CPDO are being unwound, which means lots of selling in the CDS market, even as long-only fixed-income investors are perfectly happy with their bond portfolios and have no inclination or desire to sell into a falling market.

At this point in this sorry episode there is no arbitrageur ready to take the other side of the trade by buying the cheap CDS while simulatneously selling the underlying bonds. There is no taker of the trade because no one has an inkling of when the forced selling will be over.

There’s another reason, too, why it’s not quite as simple as that. If you write protection on a corporate credit while shorting the underlying bond, what happens if that bond does end up defaulting? On many of these credits, there are many more CDSs outstanding than there are bonds. And as a result the credit is likely to end up in a Delphi situation, where the bonds rally in default. You can lose on both sides of your bet, having to pay out on your credit default swap while simultaneously being unable to cover your short on the bond. The arbitrage might be obvious, but it’s also very dangerous.

Posted in bonds and loans, derivatives | Comments Off on Will Bond and CDS Prices Ever Converge?

Will Bond and Stock Prices Ever Converge?

I feel I’ve been having this conversation for over a year now: are bonds too cheap, or are stocks too expensive? Yves Smith points out today that the FT is on the case, with John Authers taking the view that the two are bound to converge soon, and John Dizard taking the opposite case that the disparity is likely to stick around for a while.

Part of the problem is that low prices in the fixed-income market are increasingly reflecting illiquidity rather than low fundamental values. Dizard notes that this has implications for regulatory regimes which are "based on the notion that markets are liquid, continuous, and efficient":

Right now, there is a sotto voce argument in the policy world over the social utility of marking assets to market when, really, there is no market. The effect of mark to market, embodied in America in the form of FAS 157, the accounting standard, is to decapitalise the system more rapidly than new capital can be raised.

(Case in point: AIG.)

Another reason for the disconnect is that the markets have inherent differences when it comes to valuing the future. Andew Clavell, as is his wont, puts it in terms of calls and puts:

Credit instruments (corporate bonds) are essentially risk free bonds with embedded short put options on this pretax corporate cashflow. Equities are call options on after tax corporate cashflow, struck at the present value of the credit instruments.

What this means in English is that when the markets start to anticipate a future recession, bonds fall long before stocks do. Only when a recession starts to actually hit corporate profits are equity prices likely to follow suit.

Posted in bonds and loans, stocks | Comments Off on Will Bond and Stock Prices Ever Converge?

The Only Way to Win is Not to Play

A great post from Andrew Clavell today, which can be distilled down to one simple piece of advice: Just Say No to Derivatives. If you’re buying derivatives and you’re not a banker, or if you’re buying a derivatives product which was a banker’s idea and not your idea, then, well, you probably shouldn’t be.

Let’s assume you work at a Pennsylvania school board, or a Swiss private bank, an Australian life insurance company, a German corporate treasury, a UK Pension administrator or any one of thousands of other buyside entities, supposedly with sufficient expertise that an investment bank can classify you as a non-retail customer.

The more complex the structured product, the more opportunity for agents to extract fees at your expense…

Admitting you don’t know is pure alpha; you will not claim to have any edge and this may put you off involvement in the product. If you claim you do know where the fees are, banks want you as a customer. You don’t know. Really, you don’t. Hang on, I hear you shouting that you’re actually smarter than that, so you do know. Read carefully: Listen. Buster. You. Don’t. Know.

Still, the risk/reward profile of a particular structure might actually be useful to you, provided you are rewarded appropriately for the risk. Let’s use a CPDO as an example. There are always more efficient ways of assuming a similar risk profile than entering into a nicely packaged transaction – simply buying a solid vanilla floater and selling enough iTraxx/CDX OTC protection for your target yield enhancement would get you close enough not to worry much…

If this alternative is unavailable to you, for example, because your trustee documentation forbids trading derivatives, why on earth should it be OK for you to access those derivatives just becuse they were wrapped up in a funded structure with a pretty rating?

Clavell’s a former derivatives whizz: chances are, he knows what he’s talking about. Have you ever wondered how investment bank derivatives desks make so much money in a zero-sum game? It’s because, in Clavell’s words, they’re the Masterminds, and the buy side, in toto, is the Patsy. If you’re buying derivatives to hedge some risk, that’s great. If you’re using them as a profit center, not so much. Holger Härter, pay attention!

Posted in derivatives | Comments Off on The Only Way to Win is Not to Play

From Financial Supermarket to Supermarket

Citi, it seems, is exiting its consumer-finance business – at least in the key foreign markets of Japan, Mexico, and the UK, according to the WSJ. And Citi’s loss might well be Wal-Mart’s gain.

The move gives some insight into the priorities of career investment banker Vikram Pandit now that he is CEO of a global consumer bank. It’s not quite as drastic as it sounds: Citi has historically catered to the top tier of retail customers in its global operations, and the low-level consumer operations it’s now shuttering or selling are a relatively new development.

That said, however, this is a key reversal of Citi’s strategy in Mexico, where the future of banking undoubtedly lies not with the elite but rather with the underserved majority. I wouldn’t be at all surprised if the winning bidder for Citi’s Mexican operations was Wal-Mart, which already has a banking license in the country and is moving aggressively into financial services there.

It might be that Citi has proved ill-suited to judging the creditworthiness of poorer consumers; Wal-Mex, I suspect, won’t have that problem.

Posted in banking | Comments Off on From Financial Supermarket to Supermarket

Extra Credit, Wednesday Edition

What I really think of the new popular economics books: Tyler Cowen on Freakonomics and Tim Harford. Astute.

Global 10-Year Government Bond Yields: A handy country-by-country comparison.

$100 Oil: It’s Baaack…

If the Dollar Could Speak

Stuff White People Like

Posted in remainders | Comments Off on Extra Credit, Wednesday Edition

Predicting Earthquakes

InTrade has just launched a new contract:

The Exchange has listed a market on an earthquake of at least 9.0 on the Richter Scale ocurring anywwhere in the world in 2008…

This contract will settle (expire) at 100 ($10.00) if there is an earthquake measuring 9.0 or more on the Richter Scale anywhere in the world before 11:59:59pm ET on the date specified in the contract.

I’m generally a fan of prediction markets, but what on earth is the use of this one? No one has any real information on whether or not a big earthquake will strike our planet this year, which makes this contract essentially a pure gamble. I’ll happily predict that this contract sees negligible volume and crippling illiquidity for its entire lifetime.

Posted in prediction markets | Comments Off on Predicting Earthquakes

Art and Excess, Miami Edition

Jay McInerney goes to Art Basel Miami Beach:

At the Margulies Collection, a mind-boggling private trove of Modern and contemporary art housed in a humongous warehouse, I overhear this:

EUROPEAN ACCENT: That’s a portrait of Komar and Melamid.

TEXAS ACCENT: What’s Komar and Melamid?

EUROPEAN ACCENT: You just bought one of their paintings this morning.

Go read the whole thing, it’s a hoot. And I just can’t imagine that we’ll be reading stuff along these lines for all that much longer:

To a first-time visitor, the atmosphere seems like a high-end version of Filene’s Basement: a competition to find and claim the hot merchandise before your neighbor does. You get the feeling that any minute a fight may break out over who gets the big John Baldessari.

By 3 p.m., almost every booth seems to be speckled with the tiny red dots signifying sales, including Merlin Carpenter’s Christopher Wool-like black-and-white canvas emblazoned with the words "Die Collector Scum."

Posted in art | Comments Off on Art and Excess, Miami Edition

London House Price Datapoint of the Day

The average house on Courtenay Avenue, in north London, is worth £6,803,900, or $13.3 million. Well, it is very convenient for the Highgate Golf Club, after all.

In total, there are thirteen streets in London where the average house is worth more than £5 million.

(Via Alea)

Posted in housing | Comments Off on London House Price Datapoint of the Day

When the Markets are Wrong

The markets don’t always make any sense, and this headline from Bloomberg gives a prime example:

Northern Rock Credit-Default Swaps Rise on Nationalization

Yes, in the wake of the news that the Northern Rock was going to be owned by the UK government with its risk-free credit rating, the price to protect against default on Rock bonds jumped to 295 basis points. To her credit, the reporter, Abigail Moses, didn’t even attempt to come up with some spurious ex-post reason why that should be the case.

Inevitably, the swaps have now tightened, as you’d expect, moving down to 160bp. But let this be a lesson to anybody who likes to look to market reaction to real-world events: sometimes the market is just plain wrong.

Posted in derivatives | Comments Off on When the Markets are Wrong

Did Black-Scholes Cause the Housing Bubble?

Michael Lewis gets his nerd on in the March issue of Portfolio, wading into the Taleb vs Black-Scholes debate. But he actually seems to go even further than Taleb. Think of three levels of skepticism when it comes to the option market:

  1. The naive broker-dealer view: Black-Scholes enabled us to price options, and a large and efficient market is built on it.
  2. The Taleb view: Bachelier-Thorp (which predates Black-Scholes) enabled us to trade options, and a large and efficient market is built on it, and Black-Scholes is irrelevant.
  3. The Lewis view: Black-Scholes enabled us to price options, and a large market is built on it, and Black-Scholes is wrong, and so we’re all doomed.

Lewis blames a lot of things on Black-Scholes, including the housing bubble:

It wasn’t only big Wall Street firms, but a lot of small real estate speculators–otherwise known as homeowners–who, in effect, sold put options too cheaply against the risk of extreme, rare events. That many of these people literally live inside the investment that they’ve speculated on sharpens the pain but fails to drive home the point.

I’m not sure I follow this. In what sense is taking out a mortgage akin to selling a put option too cheaply? If anything, given the non-recourse nature of mortgages, it’s closer to buying a put than it is to selling one. And more generally, Lewis doesn’t persuade me that options prices in reality conform to Black-Scholes theory.

Lewis is right that if options were priced according to Black-Scholes, then we would all be doomed. But are they? Really? Taleb’s paper says that by "fudging and changing the tails and skewness by varying one parameter" in order to get Black-Scholes to accord with market reality, traders essentially render Black-Scholes moot anyway.

And personally I’m not worried about markets "for which there is no completely satisfactory pricing model," be they in options or anything else. After all, there’s no completely satisfactory pricing model for equities, either, and no one seems to be losing sleep over that.

Update: Taleb writes in the comments that "I fully agree with Michael Lewis". The idea I think is that without Black-Scholes we wouldn’t have portfolio theory, CAPM, or any of the other desiderata of financial markets which ultimately enabled the housing bubble to appear.

Posted in derivatives | Comments Off on Did Black-Scholes Cause the Housing Bubble?

This Is Financial Meltdown

Nouriel Roubini: The numbers all go to eleven. Look, right across the board, eleven, eleven, eleven and…

Larry Summers: Oh, I see. And most blogs go up to ten?

Nouriel Roubini: Exactly.

Larry Summers: Does that mean it’s grimmer? Is it any more bearish?

Nouriel Roubini: Well, it’s one grimmer, isn’t it? It’s not ten. You see, most blokes, you know, will be playing at ten. You’re on ten here, all the way up, all the way up, all the way up, you’re on ten on your blog. Where can you go from there? Where?

Larry Summers: I don’t know.

Nouriel Roubini: Nowhere. Exactly. What we do is, if we need that extra push over the cliff, you know what we do?

Larry Summers: Put it up to eleven.

Nouriel Roubini: Eleven. Exactly.

What will be the consequence of losses of over $1 trillion and, possibly, as high as $2 trillion? That would wipe out most of the capital of most of the US banking system and lead most of US banks and mortgage lenders – that are massively exposed to real estate – to go belly up. You would then have a systemic banking crisis of proportions that would be several orders of magnitude larger than the S&L crisis, a crisis that ended up with a fiscal bailout cost of over $120 billion dollars…

No wonder that some serious observers are already considering a new future scenario – however unappealing – where most of the US banking system and housing will be nationalized.

Update: By popular demand, the original.

Posted in economics | Comments Off on This Is Financial Meltdown

News Corp’s Cutest Board Member

Natalie Bancroft

"I’m not just some idiotic girl in piggytails yodeling," says Natalie Bancroft in an interview for the March issue of Portfolio, who was photographed by João Canziani. "I’m working my little butt off."

The daughter of Joyce Bancroft, a Dutch-Brazilian model, and Hugh Bancroft III, a Formula Two racecar driver, Natalie grew up splitting her time between Southern California, France, and Switzerland.

It’s worth mentioning that Natalie only got the job because the Bancroft family was so dysfunctional that it missed its deadline for nominating a family member to the News Corp board.

So unruly were the talks that the family missed an initial 30-day deadline under which it was permitted to nominate its own candidate for News Corp.’s approval, thereby contractually ceding the choice to Dow Jones’s prospective owner, News Corp. Chairman Rupert Murdoch.

The Portfolio photo editor tells me the full image is even better: go buy the magazine, when it hits your local newsstand, and see for yourself.

Posted in governance, Media, publishing | Comments Off on News Corp’s Cutest Board Member

The End of the Monolines

It looks like the end of the monolines to me. FGIC has already said it’s splitting – something which, legally, is fraught at best. Ambac is trying to raise $2 billion in new equity before, yes, splitting. And now MBIA has announced that it’s kicked out CEO Gary Dunton, replacing him with former CEO Jay Brown. Which is likely to be about as effective as reinstating Al Lord as CEO of Sallie Mae.

These are all desperate measures, taken in the face of implacable determination on the part of Eliot Spitzer to punish them harshly for letting their risky structured-products business ruin their cash-cow municipal insurance business. I don’t have an opinion on the monolines’ share prices, which could well be trading at a discount to the companies’ value in run-off. But I see very little chance at this point that these companies will be operating in their present form for much longer.

Posted in defenestrations, insurance | Comments Off on The End of the Monolines

Should the US Government Buy Distressed Bonds?

The Federal reserve, and the Federal Home Loan Banks, and Fannie Mae, and Freddie Mac, between them, have injected a huge amount of liquidity into the banking system during this credit crunch. But it’s been done in a reactive manner, without much if any strategic big-picture vision. John Cassidy has another idea. If you’re going to bail out the banks, he says why not make it explicit?

Instead of relying on Fannie, Freddie, and the F.H.L.B. to ease the credit crunch, the federal government might be well advised to intervene directly in the financial markets. One solution is for the Fed, the Treasury Department, or a new official entity to buy large amounts of mortgage-backed securities, collateralized debt obligations, and other distressed paper from financial firms at bargain-basement prices. By purchasing these assets at a discount, the government could ensure that companies pay heavily for their reckless behavior, while also injecting much-needed liquidity into the system.

Cassidy doesn’t say what the Fed and the FHLB and Fannie and Freddie should do in this scenario. Should they all start tightening, to offset the massive liquidity injection coming from elsewhere? Of course they wouldn’t. Which means that the buy-up of mortgage-backed securities would just be another reactive and seemingly-desperate attempt to inject liquidity into a banking system sufferering from a credit crunch. And as Cassidy compellingly demonstrates, we’re doing that already.

Posted in fiscal and monetary policy | Comments Off on Should the US Government Buy Distressed Bonds?

The Credit Suisse Writedown: Less Than Meets the Eye

Credit Suisse has $34 billion in CMBS, RMBS and CDO exposures. Or, hang on a minute, cut that by $2.85 billion: apparently there were some "mismarkings" going on.

There seems to be a lot of people who are very shocked by this, but it’s worth bearing in mind that all these securities are very illiquid, and that in a volatile market with wide bid-ask spreads, reasonable individuals probably can differ by more than 8.5% on the valuation of asset-backed bonds.

Posted in banking, bonds and loans | Comments Off on The Credit Suisse Writedown: Less Than Meets the Eye