Goldman: Unstoppable

We knew that Goldman Sachs had been very successful shorting the mortgage market;

we also knew that Goldman’s asset-management arm was very unsucccessful

this summer playing the stock market. And we’re also used, by now, to Goldman

setting new records for investment-bank profitability.

So the fact that Goldman Sachs earned

$3.22 billion between September and November is incredibly impressive but

also somehow unsurprising. The bit which jumped out at me was the way in which

equity trading revenues soared by 22% in the quarter, to $2.59 billion, even

as global stock-market prices and volumes were more or less flat. While the

Goldman Sachs special sauce is hard to export, it seems to be as potent and

pervasive as ever within the confines of 85 Broad Street. Just look at how they’re

doing in M&A, which helped drive financial-advisory revenues to $1.97

billion for the quarter:

Goldman, the No. 1 adviser in worldwide announced mergers and acquisitions

for the seventh consecutive year, arranged $417.9 billion of takeovers completed

during the fourth quarter, more than double a year earlier, according to data

compiled by Bloomberg.

In a way, it’s easy to understand how the likes of Ben Stein will look at these

kind of numbers with suspicion. How is it possible that Goldman can mint money

while everybody else – including Goldman’s clients – is taking a

bath? Surely there must be something nefarious going on!

But of course these numbers also prove that the last thing Goldman wants or

needs is an economic slowdown – there’s no way that Goldman is going to

arrange $400 billion of takeovers per quarter if the US economy slips into a

recession. Note that essentially $0 of that $3.22 billion came from economic

research. If you do want to look for dodgy dealings, I really don’t

think that Goldman’s economists are going to be a particularly fruitful place

to start your search.

Posted in banking | Comments Off on Goldman: Unstoppable

Extra Credit, Tuesday Edition

When a

rose is not a rose: TAF is not "just" the discount window: "To

call TAF the discount window without the stigma is like calling a person a corpse

that is not dead."

Subprime

warning signs were made of cheese: Are lunar land prices a leading indicator

of US property prices?

The

credit rating house of cards: Evan Greenberg’s Assured Guaranty bucks the

trend.

What’s Drudge

Worth? Duff McDonald reckons it’s in the $10 million to $20 million range.

Google

and Theory of Mind

TROUBLE

IN TEXAS: Huge Multifamily Owner Nears Collapse: CMBS defaults

loom as a result.

Best

Valley Boy Exam Essay Line Ever!

Please

Don’t Destroy My American Dream

Posted in remainders | Comments Off on Extra Credit, Tuesday Edition

Microlending in Mexico: Still Extortionate

BusinessWeek has a big (3,000-word) story

on Mexican microlending, by Keith Epstein and Geri Smith. It’s heavy on

the anecdote, and it comes down hard on one lender in particular: Ricardo Salinas’s

Banco Azteca, which specializes in consumer finance. I’m no fan of Salinas,

who’s a very shady businessman indeed. But I find it interesting that BusinessWeek

concentrated on Azteca.

It’s well known that Azteca is extremely profitable and charges very high rates

of interest – that’s why everybody from Wal-Mart to HSBC is trying to

muscle in on Azteca’s territory and enter the same market. But the thing is,

Azteca never really claims to be a microlender in the way that Compartamos,

say, does. Azteca is unashamedly a for-profit institution, and doesn’t even

attempt to justify its activities by pointing to the way in which they help

the poor.

Meanwhile, Compartamos, which was founded with money from the likes of CGAP,

charges just as high interest rates, but dresses them up in all manner of development

and social-welfare frippery.

This is why I welcome Wal-Mart’s move into the Mexican banking system: it’s

the only way that interest rates are really going to fall. That said, BusinessWeek’s

example of a Wal-Mart television-finance plan with an APR of 86% does give me

pause: it might be that Wal-Mart becomes just another usurer, rather than a

real force for driving lending rates down to sensible levels.

Where I have no faith at all is in the ability of the big foreign-owned Mexican

banks to help solve the usury problem. Citi’s Banamex has its Crédito

Familiar brand; HSBC has a 20% stake in Financiera Independencia. Both are an

entrenched part of the Mexican banking system, where there has historically

been very little competition on retail lending rates: there’s a very small number

of banks, and consumers find it impossible to find one which lends at a much

lower rate than the others.

If there is any hope, then, it lies either with Wal-Mart or else with Mexico’s

dysfunctional legislature, which could presumably cap interest rates were it

so inclined. I’m not holding my breath.

(Via Thoma)

Posted in banking, development | Comments Off on Microlending in Mexico: Still Extortionate

Illiquidity and Insolvency in the Commercial Real Estate Market

If you haven’t read Jesse Eisinger’s column

on the CMBS market in the latest issue of Portfolio, do check it out –

it’s very good. As a special bonus for Market Movers readers, I followed up

with him this morning, with a question about whether the market is insolvent

or "merely" illiquid. Here’s my question, followed by Jesse’s reply.

Q: Clearly demand for commercial mortgage-backed securities

has plunged, and there’s no almost no liquidity at all in the commercial-property

sector. But I’m interested: do you think this is a liquidity problem or a solvency

problem? Many of the office-building purchasers were happy with debt service

payments greater than cashflows, on the grounds that tenants were paying below-market

rates and that cashflows would improve substantially when leases expired. Do

you think that such faith was misplaced? Do you think that rents will go down

rather than up? And is there any evidence of that happening yet?

A: You are certainly right that for now, the commercial market

is facing a liquidity problem now and not a solvency problem. Delinquencies

have risen off the lows of earlier this year, but not much.

The main difference in the commercial market is that supply didn’t rise as

much as it did for the housing market.

So, does that mean if the liquidity panic subsides, the commercial and CMBS

markets will be fine? I doubt it.

The problems with the residential market didn’t start because of oversupply,

but because of bad loans — loans made to borrowers who depended on

refinancing and price appreciation to afford their loan payments. The

"values’ in the "loan-to-value" ratios that lenders used were

falsely high,

in both residential and commercial. The problems in the housing market

started before prices went down; all it took was for prices to flatten and

the subprime borrowers who had 2/28 mortgages couldn’t refinance and

couldn’t afford their loans. That’s pretty extraordinary.

So, I foresee similar things happening in the commercial real estate market.

Borrowers depended on above-normal increases — in rents or appreciation —

to afford their loans. Values rose to nosebleed levels and lending standards

dropped. Both borrowers and lenders made assumptions about future cash flows

and appreciation that were unsustainable. If rents merely fail to continue to

rise, many borrowers will have problems, I suspect. The Peter Cooper Village/Stuyvesant

town purchase is emblematic of this since the assumptions that went into the

purchase were that they would be able to wrest rent increases that were substantially

above the historical norms.

Also, it’s worth noting that around 80% of commercial loans were interest

only in recent periods, about double from four years ago. In the first quarter,

90% were IO. So these borrowers are going to be highly vulnerable to liquidity

issues. Of course, the Fed rate cuts would help in that instance, if the lending

rates follow. But if the banks and CMBS investors are being hit elsewhere, perhaps

they won’t be interested in commercial real estate loans and securities.

Moreover, prices in commercial real estate are already falling. Brian Fitzgerald

of Wachovia estimated that prices had already fallen around 5% to 10% in major

markets by late fall. That will accelerate, I am guessing.

Posted in commercial property | Comments Off on Illiquidity and Insolvency in the Commercial Real Estate Market

How Far Apart are Edwards and Obama?

Paul Krugman today lauds

the populism of John Edwards, saying that the best strategy for a Democratic

candidate is to "run with the populist tide". I wonder what he thinks

of Matt

Cooper’s latest piece in Portfolio, which says that Edwards is, not, in

fact, half as populist as Krugman might like to think:

Edwards may wax like William Jennings Bryan when he’s onstage, but behind

the scenes he sounds like an anodyne Democrat in the mold of Harry Reid….

If you look at the positions he’s taken, they’re really not that different

from those of the other Democratic candidates, even though his rhetoric is

decidedly more combative.

Krugman bases his column on differences between Edwards and Obama on the healthcare

front: Obama wants to "sit at a big table" including the insurance

and pharmaceutical companies, while Edwards says that it’s "a complete

fantasy" to think that those industries would willingly negotiate away

their power.

But I’m with Cooper on this one: Krugman’s concentrating, here, on rhetoric,

rather than substance. In reality, the differences between the Obama and the

Edwards healthcare proposals are slim, which is one reason why the debate is

moving to the how rather than the what.

Tactically, it may or may not be a good idea for Edwards to wax populist. Krugman

certainly thinks it is. I, on the other hand, think that the Obama approach

is more likely to attract Republicans who are disgusted with the Bush administration

but who fear the idea of electing a leftist. Of course, neither of us has much

in the way of political-strategy credentials – although I’d note that

Clive Crook comes

down on my side of the debate in the FT today. The substance of the candidates’

policies should be what really matters, and I do believe, with Cooper, that

there’s less of a gap between Edwards and Obama than Krugman implies.

Posted in Politics | Comments Off on How Far Apart are Edwards and Obama?

The Case Against Peak Oil

John

Cassidy has a message for the peak-oil

crowd:

The tripling of oil prices since the summer of 2003 has unleashed forces

that within the next two or three years will bring oil prices tumbling back

down to below $50 a barrel. Looking even further ahead, prices could easily

fall to $30 a barrel or even lower.

Cassidy goes into quite a lot of detail in his column as to why this should

be the case, but basically it all boils down to supply and demand: right now,

demand his high, while supply is constrained as a result of underinvestment

by oil companies when oil prices were low. Within the next few years, however,

supply will start rising: ExxonMobil alone, writes Cassidy, has invested more

than $60 billion into exploration and development over the past four years.

I’m quite sure that the peak-oil types will be entirely unconvinced by Cassidy’s

analysis, and in fact Cassidy never quite comes out and says that oil production

will actually rise significantly from its present 85 million barrels a day or

so. He does however say that "an oil glut will emerge," which amounts

to much the same thing.

I’m staying on the sidelines of this debate. I’ve never been convinced by the

apocalyptic Malthusianism coloring most of the peak-oil theories, none of which

have come true in the past. And the oil price right now does seem a little bubblicious.

But at the same time I’m actually hopeful, for climate-change reasons, that

things like tar sands in Venezuela remain untapped, and that supplies will remain

constrained. High oil prices might serve as a brake on global economic growth

in the short term, but they could also help save the planet in the long term.

Posted in commodities | Comments Off on The Case Against Peak Oil

Fishy Dealings in Trane Options

Trane is one of those invisible companies which is also omnipresent: it has

operations everywhere from the Statue of Liberty to the Kremlin, and has even

found its way into Portfolio’s offices in Times Square. It’s just been bought

for $10 billion, amidst lots of questions about possible

insider trading: nearly 45,000 call options were traded Friday, compared

to just 3,448 options traded in the entire month of November.

It’s certainly true that anybody buying those call options is likely sitting

on a very nice profit today. But what about the dealers who sold the

options? Didn’t they smell a fish? After all, options are a zero-sum game: for

every winner there’s a loser. And given the suspicious spike in volume on Friday,

I’m surprised the market-makers didn’t just close down the market after a while.

Or are they not allowed to?

How much money are we talking about here? Well, each option is (I think) on

100 shares. So if 45,000 options traded hands at a strike price of $40, that

would give the buyers the option to buy $180 million of shares at $40 each.

Those shares are now trading at $46, which corresponds to a profit of roughly

$27 million, minus the amount paid for the options. That’s big money for an

individual speculator, but it’s not going to break the bank at a broker.

Posted in derivatives | Comments Off on Fishy Dealings in Trane Options

CMBS Market Claims an Australian Casualty

Foreign stocks are becoming increasingly popular among retail investors, for

good reason, as the dollar continues to weaken. After all, if the US dollar

slumps against the Australian dollar, say, then a stock which goes nowhere in

Aussie-dollar terms can still do very well from the point of view of a US investor.

But it’s worth remembering, as the

case of Centro exemplifies this morning, that the key question is not where

a company is located, or what currency its stock is denominated in: the key

question is rather where a company does business. Centro is an Australian company,

but its shares fell 76% today as a result of its US shopping-center liabilities.

Here’s Andrew

Harrison in the WSJ:

Centro Properties — which after an aggressive acquisition spree is the fifth-largest

mall owner in the U.S., where about 65% of its assets are located — said

it will curb its growth plans there and may sell some U.S. assets…

"The conditions being experienced around the world in credit and debt

markets have made it difficult to refinance," Chief Executive Andrew

Scott told reporters in a conference call. The US$80 billion-a-month commercial

mortgage-backed securities market has "effectively closed," Mr.

Scott said.

Mish pulls no punches this morning: "kiss this company goodbye,"

he writes.

If the CMBS market remains closed, it’s certainly hard to see how Centro can

continue as a going concern: it’s managed to push

off the day of reckoning until February 15 by tapping the expensive bank-debt

market, but after that things look grim. As Jesse

Eisinger says in the latest issue of Portfolio, the CMBS market looks as

though it’s going to get much worse before it gets any better.

(HT: Joel David Parsons)

Posted in commercial property | Comments Off on CMBS Market Claims an Australian Casualty

Why Imports Should be Included in a Cap-and-Trade System

Judith Chevalier on Sunday took full advantage of the fact that her Economic

View column in the NYT coincided with the end of the Bali climate-change conference.

In it, she worries about "leakage" problems from a cap-and-trade system:

the idea that if the US caps its carbon emissions, it will essentially just

be exporting those emissions to countries such as China which impose no cap.

It’s a profound and important problem, and Chevalier

has a partial solution, which actually already exists as part of the Liberman-Warner

cap-and-trade bill, also known as the Climate Security Act.

A provision in the current version of the Climate Security Act links responsibility

to carbon consumption, not production. This idea derives from a joint proposal

by the American Electric Power Company and the International Brotherhood of

Electrical Workers. The provision requires that importers of goods from countries

without carbon caps obtain permits for the emissions resulting from the goods’

production. While this requirement could be used to protect American jobs

from foreign competition, if handled equitably, it could provide an elegant

solution to the leakage problem.

If the United States adopted a tradable permit system that treated emissions

from domestic producers identically to emissions associated with imported

goods, then products that are more emissions-intensive, whether domestic or

imported, would require more permits and thus be more expensive. Producers

in the United States and abroad would have an incentive to reduce greenhouse

gases to make their goods more competitive.

I think that "elegant" might be putting it a bit strongly: the problems

associated with measuring the carbon emissions associated with any given import

could be all but insurmountable. As Tim Harford notes, it’s pretty much impossible

to measure the carbon footprint of any given object: his

chosen item was a cappuccino, but it could just as easily have been a Chinese-manufactured

flat-screen TV.

But equally I think Dean Baker is guilty of mild utopianism when he complains

that Chevalier’s solution is second-best, and that what we should really be

aiming for is a global system of emissions caps covering every country in the

world. Well, yes, that would be nice, but it ain’t gonna happen – and

indeed Chevalier explicitly puts forward her solution "in the absence of

a binding global agreement".

In one of his Bali wrap-up pieces on Sunday, Andy

Revkin ended by quoting Stanford’s BinBin Jiang making a similar point.

Ms. Jiang also stressed that meaningful change in energy and climate policy

within the United States was critical, too. “China is clearly responsible

for the largest wedge of emissions in the future, but the United States is

still the biggest roadblock,” she said. “The U.S. is not going

to be influential by telling China what to do. It has to lead by example.”

This all recalls the nuclear-disarmament debates of the 1980s, except that

in this case unilateral action doesn’t leave a country open to an increased

chance of nuclear attack. The US can and should implement a domestic cap-and-trade

system, especially as it will never submit to a global authority setting its

caps for it. That’s the first step towards getting China to adopt a similar

approach.

(By the way, this plan is yet another reason why a

cap-and-trade system is superior to a carbon tax.)

Posted in climate change | Comments Off on Why Imports Should be Included in a Cap-and-Trade System

Extra Credit, Weekend Edition

Insolvency

is philosophy, illiquidity is fact

Church

and state on the Journal masthead

Q:

What’s the worst thing you can do with an iPhone? Chris Anderson discovers

iPhone international data roaming, and the atrociousness of AT&T customer

support.

Injecting

Liquidity: Why can’t liquidity be poured, or squirted?

Posted in remainders | Comments Off on Extra Credit, Weekend Edition

Why Bloomberg Should Embrace Cap-and-Trade

Michael Bloomberg is not a man to shy away from brainless cliché: "cities

are increasingly becoming incubators of change and drivers of innovation,"

he blathers

meaninglessly in the Economist. But at least he’s on the side of the angels

when it comes to urban policy. When it comes to climate change, however, he

seems to be increasingly, and unhelpfully,

adamant that a carbon tax is vastly better than cap-and-trade system. Now he’s

taking

that message to Bali:

Bloomberg, who addresses the conference Friday as a representative of the

world’s local governments, told a meeting with environmentalists Thursday

that carbon trading "is attractive to many politicians because it doesn’t

have that three-letter word ‘tax’."

"But it’s a very inefficient way to accomplish the same thing that a

carbon tax accomplishes," he said. "It leaves itself open to special

interests, corruption, inefficiencies."

Well, so does a tax – but a tax is much less flexible, which means a

cap-and-trade system is much better placed to react to future knowledge about

the urgency of carbon reductions.

The other problem with a tax is that it’s less likely to be passed than a cap-and-trade

system. That doesn’t bother Bloomberg, however: "that’s what leadership

is all about, and we need leaders around the world who get things done,"

he said. To which Evan Herrnstadt has a great reply:

Is it just me, or do politicians put far too much stock in their own ability

to lead America to greatness?

Bloomberg should be campaigning for any US cap-and-trade system to auction

as many of its permits as possible, which would make it tax-like and

flexible. That’s a realistic goal: the RGGI

system in the US north-east is, to most observers’ surprise, going to be almost

entirely auctioned. Bloomberg should know that it’s easier to swim with the

tide than against it, especially when there are really no compelling reasons

to prefer a carbon tax (under which emissions can continue to climb uncapped)

to a cap-and-trade system (which, by design, caps emissions at steadily-lower

levels).

Posted in cities, climate change | Comments Off on Why Bloomberg Should Embrace Cap-and-Trade

What do US Consumers Have to Fall Back On?

Even as the economy has been growing over the couple of decades, people have

been feeling increasingly insecure, perhaps because they have less and less

to fall back on. Lane

Kenworthy puts it well:

Households now appear to be more sensitive to serious short-run financial

strains — job loss, a medical problem that results in significant cost

(due to lack of health insurance or inadequate coverage), a hike in rent,

a rise in mortgage payments (as a low-interest-rate adjustable mortgage rolls

over). A generation ago a household could adjust to this type of event by

having the second adult take a temporary job to provide extra income. During

the economic boom of the late 1990s they might have been able to switch jobs

in order to get a pay increase. In the past ten years they could run up credit

card debt or take out a home equity loan.

For many households with moderate or low incomes, these strategies are now

foreclosed.

I actually think that credit-card debt might be the last stop on this particular

track – and one which we haven’t quite reached yet. Americans seem to

have been quite assiduous about paying off their credit-card debt with home

equity – not something I’d recommend, necessarily, but it does mean that

credit card debt hasn’t been rising nearly as fast as it has in, say, the UK.

Given how entrenched US consumer behavior seems to be, my feeling is that credit-card

debt is going to rise sharply next year, as home equity becomes increasingly

difficult to tap. But Kenworthy’s bigger point is absolutely spot-on.

(Via Farrell)

Posted in consumption | Comments Off on What do US Consumers Have to Fall Back On?

How Cerberus’s Cost Cutting Threatens the US Economy

There’s bad

news at Cerberus, and that could mean bad news for all of us. Cerberus has

lost a lot of money on its mortgage-servicer investments, and is now hoping

to merge its main mortgage asset, GMAC, with Chrysler’s lending operations.

According to Business Week, "by doing so, it could reap massive savings

on back office and loan processing operations, boosting returns at both GMAC

and Chrysler".

Tanta

is alarmed:

Cut back office at a mortgage servicer. Put people who can service car loans

in charge of mortgage loans. That’s exactly what we need right now…

Let me just observe that GMAC’s mortgage servicing unit was already pretty

"stripped down" in its heyday. That was its business model: cheap

servcing. I can’t wait to see what happens when you make it cheaper.

Mortgage servicers need to be beefed up right now: it takes much more work

to deal with delinquencies and foreclosures than it does to deal with lots of

people paying their mortgages on time. Cost-cutting in this environment is,

shall we say, contraindicated from a broader economic perspective. But of course

there’s no stopping Cerberus from doing whatever it wants.

Posted in housing, private equity | Comments Off on How Cerberus’s Cost Cutting Threatens the US Economy

VaR: For a Crappy Tool, It’s Really Important at Goldman Sachs

In Kate

Kelly’s narrative of Goldman Sachs’s mortgage-trading gains, thrice

the traders want to keep their bearish bets but are forced to unwind their positions

by higher-ups. What fascinates me is the way in which value-at-risk, a very

quick-and-dirty risk measure, seems to have been of paramount importance within

the highly sophisticated investment bank:

Like other Wall Street firms, Goldman weighs its financial risk by calculating

its average daily "value at risk," or VaR. It’s meant to be a measure

of how much money the firm could lose under adverse market conditions. Because

the ABX had become so volatile, the VaR connected to the trades was soaring…

Goldman’s top executives understood the group’s strategy, say people with

knowledge of the matter, but were uncompromising about the VaR. They demanded

that risk be cut by as much as 50%, these people say…

"This is the wrong price" to close out the positions, Mr. Birnbaum

snapped at a colleague assigned to help reduce risk, slamming down his phone

receiver, these people say. He was overruled…

By late July, the Bear Stearns funds had collapsed and rumors were circulating

of multibillion-dollar CDO losses at Merrill. Goldman was raking in profits.

But once again, concern was growing about VaR, the all-important measure of

risk. At one point in July, senior executives called another meeting to demand

the mortgage traders pull back, according to people familiar with the matter…

Around Labor Day, Mr. Birnbaum was asked to ratchet back one of his short

positions by $250 million, according to Hayman Capital managing partner Kyle

Bass, a client who had similar positions at the time. Mr. Bass says he made

$100 million by relieving Goldman of that particular short bet. "It appeared

to me that [the traders] constantly fought a VaR battle with the firm once

the market started to break," says Mr. Bass.

Back in October, I asked

what the pont of VaR was. Here are some of the responsees I got: "it doesn’t

accurately gage value at risk". "I presume that MS, like other investment

banks, has other, more sophisticated, risk controls." "In being so

quick and taking only historical and very little information into consideration,

it is pretty poor." "VaR’s right now are of especially little

use." "It is pretty useful for giving a gross snapshot of risk taken

to the guys in the boardroom, or at the SEC or in Basel…That’s about it."

"VaR seems at best mislabeled, and at worst completely useless for managing

risk." "It is not the end-all metric, many think it has fatal flaws."

Yet according to Kelly, this rather crappy measure is so important that on

at least three separate occasions the mortgage-trading desk was forced to unwind

its highly-profitable positions just in order to reduce its VaR. Weird.

Posted in banking | Comments Off on VaR: For a Crappy Tool, It’s Really Important at Goldman Sachs

Tax the Privately Educated

Chris

Dillow wants to tax the privately educated more heavily. I think this is

a great idea. And in fact it’s not all that far from one idea which really has

been taken seriously in the UK: a higher rate of income tax for university graduates.

The UK department of education even put out a paper

in 2003 entitled "Why not a Pure Graduate Tax?".

The losers in this kind of scheme would be private schools: middle-class parents,

worried about imposing a larger-than-necessary tax burden on their children,

would be more inclined to send their middle-class kids to state schools, thereby

improving the quality of those state schools.

Areas with many private schools, pretty much by definition, tend to be wealthy

areas. If all those wealthy parents sent their kids to the local state schools,

those local state schools would be excellent. But because the wealthy parents

send their kids to private schools instead, the local state schools often turn

out in practice to be quite bad, which only increases the desire of parents

to send their kids to private school.

This is an inefficient use of resources, especially when you consider that

the parents sending their kids to private schools are already paying for their

local public schools. It’s slightly ridiculous that the likes of Harvard and

Princeton are spend a huge amount of effort trying to prevent themselves from

becoming rich-kid ghettoes, while their private counterparts among primary and

secondary schools positively sell themselves on their rich-kid-ghetto

credentials. Let’s try to level the playing field earlier on, instead of waiting

until those kids graduate from high school.

Posted in education, taxes | Comments Off on Tax the Privately Educated

Criminals in the CEO Suite, Jewelry Edition

We’ve all heard of CEOs who are convicted of felonies and go to jail. But it’s

rarer to see the sequence reversed: convicted felons becoming CEOs. Is that

the American Dream?

In July 2004, Peter Bacanovic was sentenced

to five months in prison for lying to federal investigators. In October

2006, he gave an interview

to Landon Thomas, who described his life as "a slow trudge through the

slough of a legal and regulatory despond," and quoted him thusly:

“I am chronically sick and chronically unemployed and without any specific

plan about how to proceed next.”

And yet today we learn

that Bacanovic is the new CEO of jeweler Fred Leighton. Nice recovery, that

man!

(Via Lauren)

Posted in crime | Comments Off on Criminals in the CEO Suite, Jewelry Edition

Citi: Still Partially Insulated from SIV Losses

Alea has the scoop on Citi’s

SIVs: they’ll have to decline in value by $2.5 billion, or more than 5%,

before Citi takes a penny in losses. No wonder Citi found it relatively easy

to sell

tens of billions of dollars of the SIV assets back to the junior investors:

even this bail-in isn’t going to save those investors.

Interestingly, only 28% of Citi’s SIV assets are mortgage-related; fully 60%

of the assets are invested in the debt of financial institutions. Sure, those

institutions themselves are being hit by mortgage-related losses. But I remember

that the

first CPDO to fail was one which invested in financial-institution debt.

Maybe bank bonds are the new subprime mortgages.

Posted in banking, bonds and loans | Comments Off on Citi: Still Partially Insulated from SIV Losses

Lufthansa: No Savior for JetBlue

In the wake of Lufthansa’s $300

million investment in JetBlue, it’s worth looking at how JetBlue CEO David

Barger is doing after just over six months on the job. If you recall, he replaced

founder David Neeleman in May, mainly

because Neeleman had presided over a severe decline in JetBlue’s share price.

But since then, JBLU shares

have only fallen further: the switch of CEO seems to have made no difference

at all. And even yesterday’s spike upwards on the Lufthansa news barely registers

as a blip on the longer-term chart with its seemingly inexorable downward trend.

But just because the shares are cheap doesn’t mean that the Lufthansa investment

makes any sense: DealBook has a

good round-up of analysts scratching their heads and trying to work out

what on earth Lufthansa might be thinking here. Sure, JetBlue’s landing slots

at JFK are reasonably valuable, but a minority investment in a US domestic carrier

hardly fits in to Lufthansa’s stated strategy, especially since the move is

guaranteed to annoy Lufthansa’s existing US partner, United. Maybe Lufthansa

just wanted to take advantage of the weak dollar, and this was the only US investment

it could find.

Posted in M&A, stocks | Comments Off on Lufthansa: No Savior for JetBlue

Extra Credit, Friday Edition

The

next subprime: Reverse mortgages

Lessons

in demand elasticity: Daniel Hall on the politics of public-transport prices.

Lehman’s

2007 Bonus Pool Rises Almost 10% on Higher Revenue

Contest:

Fun with Farecast — Home for the Holidays: Paul Kedrosky finds LA-Kansas

City fares trebling over Christmas.

iPhone

EDGE browsing comparable to Nokia 3G Web

Betting

on the Next Wall Street C.E.O. Exit

Posted in remainders | Comments Off on Extra Credit, Friday Edition

Citi Bails In its SIVs

Even a stopped clock is right twice a day, or something. Somehow – more

by luck than judgment, I’m sure – I managed to call this one pretty well.

December

11:

If Citi can carve off some large chunks of its SIVs, it might be able to

reduce the rump vehicles to something digestible – at which point Citi’s

brand-new CEO can take them onto the bank’s balance sheet as part of his fresh

new strategy or somesuch. But there’s still a fair amount of pruning to go

before that happens: I don’t think Citi can really afford to take anything

like $66 billion of SIV assets onto its balance sheet right now.

December

13:

Citigroup Inc., badly bruised by mounting losses, is bailing out seven affiliated

investment entities, bringing $49 billion in assets onto its balance sheet

and further denting its capital base.

The bank said it would provide emergency support to the entities, known as

structured investment vehicles, if it can’t find buyers for their short-term

notes…

Yesterday’s move underscores how quickly Vikram Pandit, who was named Citigroup’s

chief executive Tuesday, is moving to tackle the myriad problems facing the

bank.

So Citi’s managed to further prune its SIVs from $66 billion to $49 billion

in the past few days, and is presumably actively seeking to cut them even more

if it can, maybe by dint of taking advantage of the underwhelming MLEC.

How’s Citi going to pay for this? Well, that’s the call I made yesterday –

by

cutting its dividend, of course. But what are the chances of me being right

twice in two days?

Posted in banking | Comments Off on Citi Bails In its SIVs

New Fed Window Still Carries a Little Stigma

One way of looking at the Fed’s new Term Auction Facility is that it’s the

discount window without the stigma. But stigma, it seems, is in the eye of the

beholder, and Dean Baker, for one, still seems to think that borrowing

from the TAF is a sign of weakness:

Those of us who think that Wall Street folks might not always be entirely

honest, might suspect some insiders will trade stock based on the fact that

they know certain banks have borrowed heavily through the TAF. This could

allow for substantial profits at the expense of the outsiders who don’t know

about this borrowing.

I don’t think this is realistic: TAF borrowings are likely to be at or very

close to the Fed funds rate, and there’s no stigma at all to participating in

the Fed funds market.

All the same, it might well help if some of the larger, safer, and better-capitalized

banks made their TAF borrowings public at the beginning of this new scheme –

just to help dispel any lingering idea that it’s designed only for banks in

trouble.

Posted in fiscal and monetary policy | Comments Off on New Fed Window Still Carries a Little Stigma

Evelyn Davis and Rich Zannino: Frenemies Forever!

Kenneth

Li was at the shareholder meeting where Dow Jones lost its independence

and got sold to News Corp. To nobody’s surprise, shareholder activist Evelyn

Davis was there too, and decided to turn the event into a pop quiz for outgoing

Dow Jones CEO Rich Zannino:

Davis: I had heard you’re going to go back into retailing.

Let’s see how much Mr. Zannino remembers. I am wearing an outfit by a well

known Italian designer, who has been around a lot. Can you tell me who the

designer is?

Zannino: Let’s see if I still have my touch. It looks like

Valentino to me.

Davis: My God! You are right. You haven’t lost your touch

in retail. You would be a great CEO of Neiman Marcus and I hope you take it

public again.

Davis did, of course, then follow up with the quite-reasonable observation

that Zannino’s $20 million golden parachute is "a little bit high for somebody

who has been a CEO for only about two years". But hey, maybe it means that

Neiman Marcus won’t have to pay him so much!

Posted in Media | Comments Off on Evelyn Davis and Rich Zannino: Frenemies Forever!

Why IEDs Aren’t Giffen Goods

I’m having a bit of a debate

over at Zubin’s economics blog, and rather than continue it in the comments

there, I thought I might as well hoist it up here, into its own blog entry.

Zubin’s found a chap called Matthew Hanson who claims

that he might have found a "Giffen good" – something which becomes

more popular the more expensive it gets. The title of Hanson’s paper: "Are

Improvised Explosive Devices a Giffen Good?".

Unfortunately, it seems quite clear to me that no, IEDs are not a

Giffen good, and that Hanson uses some rather shoddy logic to come to his conclusion.

There are quite a few places where Hanson’s assumptions can be challenged,

but let’s leave them to one side, and concentrate on the logical leap that Hanson

makes at the beginning of his paper:

We can treat the percentage of IED attacks that are effective as an inversely

correlated proxy for the price of an IED attack, since a decrease in the percentage

of IED attacks that are effective increases the resources necessary to conduct

an effective IED attack.

Let’s say that Iraqi insurgents, in some given time period, make A

attacks, of which E are effective. Then "the percentage of IED

attacks that are effective" is just E/A. Hanson says

that this number is "an inversely correlated proxy for the price of an

IED attack" – in other words, as E/A goes down,

the price of an IED attack – let’s call it a – goes up.

If the cost of an IED attack is a, then le’ts say the cost of an effective

IED attack is e. Since only E in every A attacks

are effective, we can say that e=aA/E.

Now let’s take another look at Hanson’s reasoning: he says that "a decrease

in the percentage of IED attacks that are effective increases the resources

necessary to conduct an effective IED attack". In other words, as E/A

goes down, e goes up.

Well, yes. Hanson’s saying here that E/A is inversely correlated

to aA/E – which is all but tautological. Most simply,

you can just hold a constant, and come to the conclusion that E/A

is, quite literally, the inverse of A/E.

What Hanson has signally failed to show is that there’s any correlation

at all, inverse or otherwise, between E/A and a

the proposition which he seems to think that he’s demonstrated.

So it seems to me that Hanson hasn’t come close to showing that IEDs, or the

cost of an IED attack, are a Giffen good. As I said in the comments to Zubin’s

original blog entry, a Giffen good isn’t just any old thing which you buy more

of and therefore spend more money on: it’s something which actually becomes

more expensive on a per-unit basis even as it becomes more popular. And for

all Hanson’s lovely charts of attack effectiveness against total IED incidents,

I don’t think he’s found any product which is behaving in a Giffen-like manner.

Update: Hanson responds, in the comments. If I understand

him correctly, he’s now saying not that IEDs are Giffen goods, but rather that

"the resources expended to cause a unit of damage" – something

which fits into "the standard consumer theory interpretation of price"

– are (or might be) Giffen goods. In which case Hanson needs to change

more than his sentence, he needs to change his title. Intuitively speaking,

something as abstract as "the resources expended to cause a unit of damage"

isn’t a good at all – a point that dsquared makes, also in the comments.

Posted in economics | Comments Off on Why IEDs Aren’t Giffen Goods

Lehman Profits From Earlier Write-Downs

There’s an art to the write-down. On the one hand, you don’t want to scare

people by writing down too much money unnecessarily. But on the other hand,

you want to be conservative, and you certainly don’t want to have to

take any subsequent write-downs because the first tranche wasn’t aggressive

enough. (Just ask Chuck Prince.) So I was heartened to see today that Lehman

Brothers seems to be getting it right: its fourth-quarter

profits included "$320 million of gains from the sale of leveraged

loans that were previously written down".

That’s the way it should be done: take a big-but-not-too-big writedown, and

then turn a profit during the following quarter when you sell those assets for

more than you wrote them down to. Let’s hope other banks will prove able to

pull off the same trick.

Posted in banking | Comments Off on Lehman Profits From Earlier Write-Downs

The Schlubby Side of Stevie Cohen

Do you know what Stevie Cohen looks like? Time

had an official photo of him in its "Time 100" feature earlier this

year. He looks well-groomed, with a clear, level gaze. But today the NYT runs

a

picture of him with Larry Gagosian, showing a very different side of the

hedge-fund billionaire altogether: a bit schlubby, a bit of a paunch, rather

too many chins. I can’t imagine he’s too happy about that photo.

Posted in hedge funds | Comments Off on The Schlubby Side of Stevie Cohen