Unreal Rally

While I’ve been trying to catch up with my RSS feeds, Jeff Cane noticed that the stock market surged today, for no discernible reason.

One big bank writes down $19 billion. Another shores up its capital to put to rest rumors that it could be the next Bear Stearns. Those are reasons to start buying up shares of financial companies?

Jeff is wary about reading too much into this rally; I am too. I particularly mistrust this kind of thing:

It’s the first trading day of the second quarter. The market slumped in the two previous quarters, and it has been three decades since it has had three consecutive down quarters.

There’s a hell of a lot of once-in-every-thirty-years events going on right now. If someone offers me better-than-even odds, I’ll happily bet on a stock-market decline in Q2. Not because I think it’s going to happen, but just because I think it’s a coin-toss out there.

Posted in stocks | Comments Off on Unreal Rally

Most People Will Never Understand What Happened to Bear Stearns

I’m catching up on a lot of material from the past week and a half or so, most of which is a little stale by now. But Deborah Solomon’s NYT interview with former Treasury secretary Paul O’Neill is still very interesting – and not for what O’Neill says, either. Here’s a sequence of Solomon questions, with the answers snipped out:

Do you think it was appropriate for the Federal Reserve to lend a helping hand to Bear Stearns and save a private investment company from its own bad decisions? …

No it wasn’t. It was purchased by JPMorgan, which will keep it alive. …

It’s so hard to understand how the subprime mortgage crisis has triggered a financial crisis of global proportions. …

Instead of helping Bear Stearns, why doesn’t the Fed help out homeowners? …

What do you think of James Cayne, the former Bear Stearns C.E.O., who was off playing bridge as the company was collapsing? …

But as the former C.E.O. of Alcoa and a current adviser to the Blackstone Group, what do you make of the general decline in corporate leadership, which seems less invested these days in the old paternal model of social responsibility than in personal greed?

Now I’m aware that the interview was "condensed and edited" by Solomon, but even so she’s perfectly happy painting herself as someone who is happy to flatly contradict O’Neill in one question, and then admit that she’s actually pretty clueless in the next.

The interview reminds me of nothing so much as the Onion story headlined "JPMorgan Chase Acquires Bear Stearns In Tedious-To-Read News Article", which would seem to encapsulate the popular grasp of goings-on in the financial world:

Successfully adding yet another infuriating block of text to an already indecipherable paragraph, some investors said they hoped to stave off bankruptcy for Bear Stearns, which, during last year’s impossible-to-write-about mortgage crisis, saw its value depreciate almost as quickly as readers’ interest in this story.

Jimmy Cayne playing bridge? That we can understand. Ach, this is all a case of greedy billionaires being bailed out by the taxpayer while ordinary homeowners suffer. Must be.

I don’t think either would really appreciate the comparison, but Deborah Solomon seems to have an attitude not all that far removed from that of Mo Tkacik. I think it’s grounded in zero-sum thinking: if ordinary people are hurting, then the rich people must be somehow stealing the masses’ rightful money, so let’s just blame the bridge-playing rich for whatever happens to ail us.

And in point of fact I have a fair amount of sympathy with to that point of view. I don’t like it when it gets trumpeted in the NYT from a position of ignorance, but it’s probably a good idea for those of us knee-deep in financial minutiae every day to be reminded just how little most people understand of what’s going on.

Posted in banking, Media | Comments Off on Most People Will Never Understand What Happened to Bear Stearns

Gold: Too Volatile to be a Safe Investment

Eddy Elfenbein notes today that gold has dropped below $900 an ounce. Gold funds in general are suffering, with the biggest of them all, the $8.2 billion Merrill Lynch World Gold, down 10% in March. But they’re still bullish:

The Midas Fund, managed by Thomas Winmill in New York, fell more than 11 percent last month, leaving it 4.1 percent down this year.

“As the gold price recovers and exceeds recent highs, we expect Midas Fund to outperform,” Winmill said in an e-mailed message yesterday.

When gold exhibits this kind of volatility, it’s not for risk-averse investors, no matter how much the goldbugs say that it’s a safe haven. Given how risk averse the IMF is, I think that selling the Fund’s gold reserves is still a pretty good idea.

Posted in commodities | Comments Off on Gold: Too Volatile to be a Safe Investment

Sovereign Wealth Funds: Yes, They Really Are That Big

Bob Davis has got his hands on a leaked paper by the Milken Institute’s Christopher Balding, in which Balding claims that sovereign wealth funds might not have as much money as everybody seems to think that they have.

Without seeing the paper it’s hard to judge it, but it seems that Balding is relying on official US Treasury data for the size of sovereign wealth holdings. And as Brad Setser has repeatedly shown, that data massively understates the real amount of wealth at play. Specifically, it excludes all the monies that sovereign wealth funds have outsourced to banks and fund managers.

The Milken Institute says that it’s sent the paper out for peer review; when a final version comes out, this large possible problem with it might well be fixed. But for the time being it’s still reasonably safe to assume that sovereign wealth funds really do have trillions of dollars in assets, and not just the few hundred billion that Balding has found in the Treasury data.

Posted in economics | Comments Off on Sovereign Wealth Funds: Yes, They Really Are That Big

Blogonomics: Valleywag’s Pay

Jeff Bercovici has already picked up on the mini-tantrum thrown this morning by Valleywag’s Jordan Golson. Valleywag, of course, is part of Gawker Media, which pays its writers on the basis of how many pageviews they get. But that "pageview rate", or PVR, gets reset every quarter. Jordan doesn’t know what the new quarter’s rate will be, which means he doesn’t know how much he’s being paid.

Jordan’s headline is provocative: "I don’t know what my salary is," he says. Gawker Media editorial honcho Noah Robischon responds in the comments, calling the headline innacurate. I call this one in favor of Golson. What’s happened in this case is that Golson’s take-home pay is so much larger than his base salary that his base salary ($2,500 a month) has become basically irrelevant. Instead, he’s been relying entirely on his PVR of $9.75 per thousand pageviews – a rate which has seen him taking home more than $4,000 a month so far this year. For Golson, then, his realistic base salary is in the $4,000 range – much higher than the $2,500 which Robischon is referring to.

The problem here could have been partially fixed if Robischon had decided to give Golson a more realistic base salary to begin with. But Robischon’s boss, Nick Denton, wants fixed salaries to be as low as possible: he hates it when a writer doesn’t justify his salary with pageviews, and the best way of ensuring that situation never arises is to make the fixed salaries as low as possible.

But if writers are earning a great deal more than their monthly base every month, the quarterly PVR cut translates into an immediate pay cut. And as Choire Sicha points out in Golson’s comments:

The giant flaw in this is, in the words of one psych prof: "The psychological impact of losing something is about 2.5 times as great as the psychological impact of gaining the same thing." And I don’t think the company understands that employees react badly to uncertainty.

If things go according to Denton’s master plan, Gawker Media writers see their take-home pay rise steadily from month to month. Every three months, there’s a small step down, but over the long term the secular increase in pageviews more than makes up for the quarterly decrease in PVR. Yet even in this best-case scenario what the writers remember – and feel most stingingly – are the pay cuts (imposed from above) rather than the pay rises (which accrue from their own blogging success).

The Denton plan is particularly brutal in the case of Wonkette, where PVRs are being slashed quite dramatically this election year. On a logical level, this makes sense, but on a psychological level it can be extremely demoralizing.

My feeling is that if PVRs change quarterly, then monthly base salaries should as well. If Gawker had been smart about this, they would have told Golson his new PVR in advance – and at the same time given him a sizeable bump in his monthly base pay. The total amount they end up paying him wouldn’t have been any higher, but he would probably have been a lot happier about it.

Update: Valleywag’s stats were briefly down, they’re now back up. It turns out that Golson got 557,469 pageviews in March, which equates to a total paycheck of $5,435. That’s well over double his base pay. His colleague Nicholas Carlson earned $9,025 for the month, in which Valleywag as a whole got just over 5 million pageviews. That’s an impressive rate of growth, but it does help explain why Denton might want to bring Valleywag’s PVR down towards the levels seen in the rest of Gawker Media.

Update 2: Henry Farrell has some very intelligent things to say about all this.

Posted in blogonomics | Comments Off on Blogonomics: Valleywag’s Pay

The H1-B Fiasco, Redux

The H-1B fiasco is back! Last year, faced with

123,480 applications in two days for a pool of just 65,000 H-1B visas, the Bureau of Citizenship and Immigration Services was forced to run a lottery to see who would get a visa and who wouldn’t. With a full year to decide what to do about this year’s tranche of applicants, the Bureau has gone back to the drawing board, and decided that this year it will, er, run a lottery again.

The big problem here is that the 65,000 number is far, far too low. As I said last year:

For three years after 2001, the H-1B quota was raised by Congress to 195,000 – and even that was too low. That it’s now back to 65,000 is a national embarrassment. Compared to most immigrants, holders of H-1Bs are highly educated, pay lots of taxes, and benefit both the economy and their local communities. The cost of educating them has been borne elsewhere, and now they want to give the benefits to the US. As a nation of immigrants, it should be welcoming them with open arms.

Critics of the present system complain that too many H-1Bs go to foreign-owned companies. They also complain about the visa lowering wages:

Ron Hira, a professor of public policy at the Rochester Institute of Technology, said that gaps in the rules had allowed technology companies, including American ones, to misuse the program.

“Basically, H-1B has been thoroughly corrupted,” Mr. Hira said. “Under H-1B you could be forced to train your own replacement,” he said, speaking of American workers.

Mr. Hira pointed out that current rules do not require employers to prove a labor shortage by advertising jobs or recruiting in the United States. He said wages established for H-1B technology workers were below market levels in this country, allowing companies that use the visas to gain a competitive advantage and lowering wages over all.

As Dean Baker quite rightly points out, it’s far from clear why high-tech workers should be insulated from foreign competition when steelworkers aren’t. And I think that Hira in any case is simply wrong: I’m pretty sure that you do need to advertise locally the jobs for which you’re looking to hire an H-1B worker instead.

The immigration debate is always fraught. But most of the time there’s general agreement that the US should be open to high-quality legal immigration. That’s exactly what the H-1B provides, which is why the H-1B program should be vastly expanded.

Update: Be sure to read the comments on this post. They’re really good.

Update 2: Hira is in fact right: you don’t need to advertise a job you’re looking to fill with an H-1B worker. But there are still labor market protections:

Any employer wishing to bring in an H-1B worker

must attest in an application to the DOL that the employer will pay the H-1B worker

the greater of the actual wages paid other employees in the same job or the prevailing

wages for that occupation; the employer will provide working conditions for the H-1B worker that do not cause the working conditions of the other employees to be

adversely affected; and there is no strike or lockout.

Update 3: Francisco Torralba has some very intelligent words on the subject.

Posted in immigration | Comments Off on The H1-B Fiasco, Redux

How to Make Money from Losing Money, UBS Edition

UBS is the latest bank to see its share price rise in the wake of an absolutely enormous write-down. The $19 billion write-down announced today almost doubles the write-downs taken since the third quarter of 2007, and, in a move reminiscent of Sandy Weill being replaced by Chuck Prince, chairman Marcel Ospel is retiring to make way for his general counsel.

So what does the stock market like here? Frankly I’m not sure. A Sfr15 billion rights issue will do wonders for UBS’s battered balance sheet, but it will also dilute existing shareholders enormously. My feeling is that investors are rewarding UBS for getting out of its ostrich pose. But if new chairman Peter Kurer doesn’t start showing some impressive results sharpish, I suspect that the market will prove to have very little patience for him.

Posted in banking, stocks | Comments Off on How to Make Money from Losing Money, UBS Edition

Lehman: Still Ready to Lend Megabucks

I’m back from holiday, and it seems there’s a 218-page report I Really Ought To Read. Do I hafta? In the meantime, I note that Lehman’s hitting the markets up for cash. Obviously Lehman, like all investment banks, reckons that now’s a good time to have excess liquidity. Which is why I was fascinated to find this in my daily email from Latin Finance yesterday:

Brazilian miner Vale, which last week halted talks with Xstrata for an up to $90bn takeover of the Swiss company, managed to secure a total of $71bn in commitments from banks to support the transaction if it had gone through, says a banker on the deal. The staggering figure, unprecedented in LatAm, highlights the fact that top quality corporates with strong relationships in hot sectors still have ready access to a lot of cash, albeit at higher prices. Santander, Calyon and HSBC committed the biggest tickets, of $7.3bn each, while BNP, Citi, Credit Suisse, Calyon, HSBC, RBS and Lehman took lead manager tickets of $5bn and up.

Lehman sticks out like a sore thumb here: everyone else is a commercial bank whose business is lending money. Lehman, the sole pure investment bank on the list, really has no business promising $5 billion to Brazilian miners, especially at interest rates which might well be lower than Lehman’s own cost of funds right now. If I was Lehman CFO Erin Callan, I’d be breathing a huge sigh of relief right now that the Vale-Xstrata deal has fallen through and I don’t need to write that $5 billion check, even if it did come with hefty advisory fees attached.

Posted in banking, bonds and loans | Comments Off on Lehman: Still Ready to Lend Megabucks

Ben Stein Watch: March 30, 2008

Ben Stein is back in the NYT again this week: after filing just one column in all of February, he’s managed no fewer than four in March. Doesn’t he have a film to promote or something? Stein this week turns in one of his more sensible efforts (which isn’t saying much), but that doesn’t prevent him from writing passages like this:

Plan for living more frugally. This is not easy for some of us. “What were once vices are now habits,” as the Doobie Brothers once said. This is true for millions of us, but we simply cannot escape the logic and power of arithmetic.

We cannot live forever on more than we have in principal and interest (or earnings ) and pensions. If that means no more second homes, or no more third cars, so be it.

No comfort is worth putting yourself in genuine fear of poverty. For me, your humble scribe, this is a vicious problem, but at some point, it must be solved.

Apparently Stein’s "genuine fear of poverty" is "a vicious problem". Does he even know what poverty is? Remember that when he talks about "second homes", he means homes plural: in a column for this very website headlined "It Ain’t Easy Being Rich", Stein enumerated among his holdings "a home in Beverly Hills, a home in Malibu, a writing retreat in Rancho Mirage, another in a high-rise condo in West Hollywood, and a pied-ßøßø-terre in Washington, D.C., and some others I won’t mention right now".

Stein does have a problem, and quite a vicious one, which is that he has become the worst kind of propagandist in the promotion of his new film. On a conference call Friday he claimed that "Darwinism is politics masquerading as science," and was quite unambiguous about what kind of politics he was talking about: "If I’d had my way about this movie, I’d have had much more about Nazi Germany," he said.

Stein is becoming a sick and unfunny joke at this point, and the NYT, by association, is the butt of that joke. Nick Kristof and many other reporters do a very good job reporting on real poverty for the New York Times; I hope they’re barraging their editors right now with complaints about how Stein is trivializing an extremely serious problem. Given the level of intellectual honesty that Stein displays in his new film, it shouldn’t be too hard at this point for the NYT to kill his column permanently.

Posted in ben stein watch | Comments Off on Ben Stein Watch: March 30, 2008

Ben Stein Watch: March 23, 2008

Now that I’ve left the desert and I have proper internet access rather than trying to update the blog from my iPhone, I can finally get around to Ben Stein’s NYT column from Sunday. Given that I’m still on holiday, though, I’ll allow myself a slightly broader remit this time round. I’ll explain just how Stein is wrong, as usual. But I also want to ponder Stein’s bigger shtick, as well as my own.

Stein has two main points in this column. The first is merely wrong: he says that as far as we know "we are not in a recession," and that "as a matter of definition, we simply cannot be in one yet". This is simply false. Stein is correct that a recession is defined as two consecutive quarters of negative growth, and that growth in the fourth quarter was positive. But that doesn’t mean we can’t be in a recession now: we’re in the first quarter, and if both Q1 and Q2 growth are negative, then the recession will have started in Q1. Alternatively, if Q4 growth is revised downwards into negative territory, then a recession could have started as early as Q4. We don’t know for sure, but it just makes no logical sense to move from "we don’t know whether X" to "therefore not X". (Would that Stein felt the same way about the existence of God: he might not have made the world suffer through his latest film.)

Stein’s second point is more insidious. It, too, is wrong: he complains, essentially, about some shadowy cabal of investment bankers and hedge-fund managers who between them control so much money that they can move the market and bring down entire financial institutions on little more than a whim. Why is the market melting down now? He’s willing to go out on a limb:

The new part is the hedge funds and the changing of Wall Street from a financing entity to a market manipulation entity. The new part is hedge funds with (supposedly) $1.5 trillion in capital, immense hedge funds within banks and investment banks. The new part is that they have so much money and so much selling power that they can do what capitalists really want and love to do: to make money not by betting on the markets, but by controlling the markets, by putting so much sell side (and occasionally buy side) firepower in play that they know they will move the markets. This takes all that annoying uncertainty out of it.

The task of the hedge funds is to find a weak spot in the market, and to put so much pressure on it that they can move it down, scare other players into selling (with the endless help of guileless journalists), wreak havoc with the markets’ indexes and then create that much more selling. Once the process starts rolling, it’s shooting fish in a barrel.

Just think of what the short sellers did to Bear Stearns.

Stein has been here before, but back then he was a bit vaguer. Now he’s blaming the demise of Bear Stearns on "short sellers", which is just ridiculous. There was a run on the bank, and yes hedge funds were involved. But the number of short sellers was tiny: if a bank suffers a run, you don’t need short sellers for the stock to collapse.

Stein simply refuses to believe that anybody is really worried; refuses to countenance that the fears in the market are genuine as opposed to manufactured by secretive billionaires for the purpose of their further enrichment. At least he’s consistent. His new film is premised largely on a repudiation of Occam’s Razor: the basic verities of Darwinism must, he thinks, be treated equally with any unfalsifiable crackpot theory which necessitates all manner of imaginable-yet-unobserved intervention by an entity of inhuman power.

When it comes to the collapse of Bear Stearns, Stein does something almost identical. The obvious and true narrative is one of fear: if a brokerage is looking after your assets, and there’s some small chance that the brokerage in question is going to go bust, then it’s perfectly rational to move those assets elsewhere. If everybody does that at once, the brokerage will go bust.

The problem for Stein is that in a fear narrative there’s no one really to blame. Stein feels the need to point fingers, and in return that means he needs a greed narrative instead. And there’s only one way to construct a greed narrative out of falling markets: short sellers! Never mind that the main role of secretive billionaires in this story was to lose money (Joe Lewis): Stein’s convinced that there are some other even more secretive billionaires, with even more money, who were shorting Bear’s stock and making a fortune. And the great thing about this theory – just like any conspiracy theory, and just like Intelligent Design – is that it’s impossible to disprove.

But the unfalsifiability of conspiracy theories is always just a means to an end – the end being the uncovering of said conspiracy, which is one in which a small group of powerful men stays rich and powerful, even if that means destroying the hopes and dreams of ordinary people. In other words, conspiracy theories are by their very nature populist: they thrive on blaming powerful others for the real or imagined travails affecting the masses. In that sense they’re a repudiation of the meritocratic American Dream. You thought you believed in science, or in fair and efficient markets? More fool you for being hoodwinked!

And it’s largely for that reason that I believe Stein has no place in the august pages of the New York Times. It’s not only that he’s wrong; it’s also that he’s anti-enlightenment, in a publication whose first purpose is to bring truth to its readers. Stein’s bit about the "guileless journalists" is a regular feature of his column: he uses his NYT real estate regularly to paint the NYT itself, along with other media outlets, as being but a pawn of the powerful. And again he does so not in any falsifiable way: he’s much happier using insinuation and innuendo to tap into the inchoate fears of the poor that they’re being taken advantage of. And that’s something which really doesn’t belong in the business section of a paper desperately trying to be taken seriously by financial professionals.

Which brings me to my last post – the one from the iPhone. Last week, I posted a blog entry with the headline "Why It’s Safe to Bet Against Joe Lewis", in which I said that it was a good idea to bet that Bear Stearns stock was going to fall. I concluded:

I see only one conceivable way in which Bear gets taken over for much more than $2 a share (or a bit more than that now, as the offer is in stock, and JP Morgan’s stock has risen since the offer was made). And that’s if Jamie Dimon unilaterally decides to raise his offer, deciding that spending a couple of hundred million dollars more on the acquisition is worth it if it avoids months of legal headaches. And Dimon’s said quite explicitly that he won’t do that. In this deal, Dimon’s the winner, and Lewis is the loser. If you want to bet on the loser, feel free. But don’t expect to make any money doing so.

As we all know, the following weekend Jamie Dimon decided to unilaterally raise his offer, and I put up a short and mildly snarky iPhone post saying that I regretted the error. But in truth I don’t regret anything. I’m a blogger, not a hedge-fund manager or the editor of an investment newsletter. I make no bets in the markets, and I lay no claim to "alpha". All I do is call things as I see them. If that’s valuable to you, great. But one thing I’m quite proud of is that sometimes I’m going to be right and sometimes I’m going to be wrong, and most of the time it’s going to be very easy to tell the difference. I’ve been wrong about many things in the past; hell, in the MBS market alone I’ve been wrong many times over. When I’m wrong, I try to learn from my mistakes, and you can’t do that without admitting your mistakes in the first place.

Every so often I get comments on this blog saying that I’m an idiot because something I said has turned out to be wrong. But that just doesn’t make sense to me. The real idiots, to me, are people like Ben Stein. Stein makes factual errors, but that doesn’t make him an idiot. What makes him an idiot is his evident belief in his own infallibility, to the point at which he clearly doesn’t allow the NYT’s editors to do even a cursory fact-checking run over his copy before it’s published. And what makes him more of an idiot is his steadfast refusal to engage with his critics – indeed, he will even stoop to outright deception in order to avoid having any kind of real debate.

Maybe the reason I feel so strongly about Stein is that we are both, in our own ways, opinion journalists. Stein is of the "here’s my opinion" school; I, on the other hand, thrive on debate. Every day I link to something I disagree with, and tease out exactly where the areas of disagreement are and why I think the other person is wrong. The end result, for the reader, is something much richer and more nuanced, especially when all the people I’m linking to are busy linking away themselves.

With surprising frequency, differences in the blogosphere end up being settled by events. On the question of Wall Street bonuses I was right and Jesse Eisinger was wrong; on the question of the Bear Stearns share price I was wrong and Jim Ledbetter was right. In both cases, the debate itself was illuminating. The problem with Ben Stein is that he doesn’t listen, he doesn’t debate; instead, he simply panders. It’s an attitude which might go down well among fundamentalist Christians, but it’s not one which belongs in the New York Times.

Posted in ben stein watch | Comments Off on Ben Stein Watch: March 23, 2008

A Quick Note From Marfa

I said last week that BSC was going either to $2 or to $0. I regret the error.

Posted in stocks | Comments Off on A Quick Note From Marfa

Taking a Break

At the end of the most hectic week in Market Movers’ year-long history, I’m off on holiday for the rest of the month. Posting will be sporadic at best for the remainder of March, and likely nonexistent until Wednesday. Unless I’m simply incapable of going cold turkey, of course. We’ll see.

Posted in Announcements | 1 Comment

Blogonomics: Gawker’s Payroll, Redux

You wanna know how much Gawker writers get paid? Well, let me tell you. Remember that they don’t really get salaries any more, just advances. And it’s been widely reported that bloggers on the flagship Gawker site get $7.50 per thousand pageviews. All we need to know now is how many pageviews they get, and, well, it turns out there’s a public webpage detailing that information.

In the month of February, Gawker’s most-read blogger was Richard Lawson, with 1,208,704 pageviews: he earned $9,065 for the month. Ryan Tate, in the number-two spot with 970,219 pageviews, earned $7,277. The least-read blogger was Nick Douglas, who got 267,570 pageviews. My guess is that his base salary is more than $2,007 per month, which means that he can’t be feeling very secure right now – especially since he’s bottom of the league table in March as well.

Total payroll for the month of February was $33,294, plus some extra for people whose base pay is more than their earn-out: call it $40,000 in total. Gawker received a total of 14,088,429 pageviews in February, which means that Denton is paying his writers about $2.84 per thousand pageviews that he receives.

In any case, take that $40,000 per month, and distribute it among six bloggers: that works out to an annualized $80,000 apiece, on average. Which is really not at all bad for the kind of people Gawker hires, who are often talented but unproven twentysomethings.

You can reasonably expect that the $80,000 figure is going to remain roughly constant, even if pageviews steadily increase. The pageview rate ($7.50, at Gawker) gets reset every quarter, and is calculated essentially by taking the editorial budget and dividing it by the number of eligible pageviews. So if pageviews go up, then the pageview rate goes down: you can be sure that the staff over at Gizmodo, seven of whom got over a million pageviews, and one of whom (Jesus Diaz) got 3.1 million pageviews in February, don’t get paid $7.50 per thousand.

Still, cruising around the Gawker Media stats pages (just put /stats onto the end of the domain in question) does make you realize how the Gawker-obsessed media misses much more important writers for the network as a whole. Do you know who Adam Pash is? He’s a blogger at Lifehacker; he got 5.2 million pageviews in January. Dashiell Bennett got 2.8 million pageviews at Fleshbot.

I’d assume that Pash and Diaz are making comfortable six-figure incomes blogging, and that a good few of the "site leads" (Gina Trapani, Brian Lam) are as well. Conversely, some of the less popular bloggers are likely getting paid $50-60,000 per year.

Gawker Media as a whole is holding reasonably steady on about 210 million pageviews per month. If Denton’s payroll is $3 per thousand pageviews (remember he has to pay his site leads as well, on every site other than Gawker), that would mean he’s paying about $630,000 a month in editorial salaries – which is pretty close to the number I arrived at at the end of my first post on this subject.

What are the effects of making bloggers’ pageview figures so transparent not only to themselves but also to the general public? I can’t help but feel that it must mean more competitiveness, and less helpfulness and collegiality, among bloggers on any given site. With the total editorial budget largely preset, there is a zero-sum game being played between bloggers, over time: a successful blogger’s gain will be an unsuccessful blogger’s loss. It’s certainly not an atmosphere I’d like to work in.

Posted in blogonomics, pay | Comments Off on Blogonomics: Gawker’s Payroll, Redux

The JP Morgan-Bear Stearns Option Agreement

Remember Exhibit A, the stock option agreement between JP Morgan and Bear Stearns which no one made public? Well, it’s finally been filed with the SEC. And it says exactly what everybody’s been saying that it says, only in legalese rather than English:

1. (a) Issuer hereby grants to Grantee an unconditional, irrevocable option (the “Option”) to purchase, subject to the terms hereof, up to 29,000,000 fully paid and nonassessable shares of Issuer’s Common Stock, par value $1.00 per share (“Common Stock”), at a price of $2.00 per share (the “Option Price”); provided, however, that in no event shall the number of shares of Common Stock for which this Option is exercisable exceed 19.9% of the Issuer’s issued and outstanding shares of Common Stock without giving effect to any shares subject to or issued pursuant to the Option.

One thing I haven’t seen reported: in order for JP Morgan to be able to exercise its option, it’s not enough for shareholders simply to vote against the deal. There also needs to be a Subsequent Triggering Event, which is essentially that someone else has bought at least 20% of Bear Stearns. Which means that if shareholders vote no without a better offer on the table, JP Morgan can’t automatically hold a revote in the knowledge that it has an extra 19.9% stake.

Posted in banking, M&A | Comments Off on The JP Morgan-Bear Stearns Option Agreement

Extra Credit, Friday Edition

James Cayne risks lawsuit as he seeks counter-offer for Bear Stearns: Is this why he didn’t sign the merger agreement?

More on debt and net worth

Fed funds question: Krugman asks if Fed funds can go much lower. I think they can – and that Treasury rates can go negative.

The Liquidity Trap Cometh…: Brad DeLong looks at the credit markets.

A crisis? Or a mere recession? An Indian pundit puts things in perspective.

Clarke and Dawe: the comic duo you can bank on: John Bird and John Fortune, with Aussie accents.

Posted in remainders | Comments Off on Extra Credit, Friday Edition

Lehman: The Eisinger Effect

If you look at the one-day chart of Lehman’s stock price today, you’ll see that it was up a coupla bucks, happily crusing along, until early afternoon. Then, suddenly, in the last two hours of trading, Lehman’s stock skyrocketed in high volume, ending up more than 15% on the day, to a very healthy (by current standards) 1.23 times book value. What happened in mid-afternoon to boost the stock so much? Well, Jesse Eisinger published a very skeptical article about Lehman’s balance sheet, in the wake of similar questions from Andrew Clavell about HBOS. Maybe Jesse is a contrarian indicator!

Posted in banking, stocks | Comments Off on Lehman: The Eisinger Effect

PDCF: A Veritable Firehose of Liquidity

We knew the Fed’s new Primary Dealer Credit Facility, where it lends money to investment banks, was being used:

Morgan Stanley borrowed $2 billion Tuesday from the Fed using "pretty liquid" assets as collateral, said Chief Financial Officer Colm Kelleher. "We didn’t need to, but I felt we should to show there was no stigma, and show support for what the Fed had done," he said.

Goldman Sachs Group Inc. tapped it for $100 million Tuesday. Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. also used it.

But on this kind of a scale?!

PDCF borrowings, the scheme announced last Sunday night, are running at $28.8 billion as of last night.

I think it’s safe to assume that substantially all those borrowings took place after the rate cut on Tuesday. And "last night" is Wednesday night. So that’s $29 billion in borrowings in two days. Clearly the market was thirsty! Any idea who the biggest borrowers were?

Posted in fiscal and monetary policy | Comments Off on PDCF: A Veritable Firehose of Liquidity

Howard Marks, The Optimistic Bear

Peter Lattman has the latest memo from Howard Marks, and it’s not pretty. If you want the most bearish soundbite, this is it:

We’ve had collapses in the past, but never so broad-gauged and systemic.

Marks foresees some drastic measures on the regulatory front:

A holiday from capital

requirements would allow regulated financial institutions to take writeoffs and clear their

balance sheets without having to worry about falling below minimums. They might even

try suspending mark-to-market accounting.

All the same, he’s convinced that we’ll get though this somehow.

The things

one would do to gird for the demise of the financial system will turn out to be huge

mistakes if the outcome is anything else . . . and chances are high that it will be.

Which means that, sooner or later, things are going to stop getting worse and start getting better:

One of these days, the herd will give up on there

being a solution. And unless the financial world really does end, we’re likely to

encounter the investment opportunities of a lifetime.

Howard Marks has demonstrated that he’s good at calling those inflection points. But unless you’re Howard Marks, you might not want to try this at home.

Posted in economics, investing | Comments Off on Howard Marks, The Optimistic Bear

Solvency Doesn’t Matter

Northern Rock was not insolvent when it collapsed. Bear Stearns was not insolvent when it collapsed. HBOS, victim of a bear raid yesterday, is not insolvent either. This is meant to reassure us? It doesn’t reassure Andrew Clavell.

Posted in banking | Comments Off on Solvency Doesn’t Matter

Homes as Investments

Ben Bernanke lives with his wife and two children in a house on Capitol Hill. Oh, wait, scratch that: according to Brendan Murray,

Ben Bernanke lives with his wife and two children "in an investment that’s turned cold".

Maybe it’s just me, but I find this kind of reporting rather irksome. Bernanke is chairman of the Federal Reserve, he works in Washington, he has a family, it makes perfect sense for him to own a house on Capitol Hill, to live in. Not as an "investment", just as a place where he can make a home and provide comfortable shelter for his family.

Historically, homes were not considered "investments". You bought a home because you needed a place to live, and you paid it off slowly over time with the help of a 30-year mortgage. Investments were stocks, or mutual funds: things you bought in the hope and expectation that they would go up in value and you could make money by selling them for more than you paid.

Then, of course, came the housing bubble, which meant that homes became much more expensive – much more expensive than the alternative, which was renting. And the only way to justify the vast extra expense of buying over renting was to factor in house-price appreciation. At that point, there was an element – but only an element – of "investment" to any house purchase. Flippers and speculators, of course, were all about housing-as-an-investment, but they were always a small minority of home buyers, and clearly Bernanke doesn’t belong in their ranks.

The biggest unanswered question about the housing crash is what is going to be done by people who are able to pay non-recourse mortgages which are larger than the value of their homes. The biggest bears, like Nouriel Roubini, think that as many as 50% of those people will walk away from their homes – which is the rational thing to do if you think of your house as an investment. Personally, I think the percentage will be much smaller. Can you imagine Ben Bernanke uprooting his family and defaulting on his mortgage if the value of his house falls a lot further? It’s unthinkable. In fact, think of the families you know with mortgages, and ask yourself how many of them would default and suffer through foreclosure just because doing so works out cheaper than staying current on the mortgage. They might have hoped, when they bought their houses, that prices would continue to rise. But that doesn’t mean they were making an investment, as one might in shares of General Electric, one which you can always give up if it turns sour.

Homes – primary residences especially – really are different from any other investment. Yes, default rates on first mortgages are at historically high rates, and they might well rise further; certainly the RMBS market is pricing an extremely high number of future defaults. But that doesn’t mean homes have become nothing more than investments. At least, I hope it doesn’t.

(HT: Alea)

Posted in housing | Comments Off on Homes as Investments

Credit: Still Hairy

The TED spread is above 200bp, and now repo rates on three-month Treasury bills have gone negative. What does that mean in English? Markets are broken. And once markets break, the healing process tends to be long and painful. The stock market might be up today, but this doesn’t look good to me.

Posted in bonds and loans | Comments Off on Credit: Still Hairy

The Political Independence of the Fed

As anybody who’s ever read about a Supreme Court nomination knows, the business of appointing top judges has become highly political. But when it comes to the Federal Reserve, it seems that presidential appointees are still chosen the old-fashioned way: on their merits, rather than on their politics.

Mark Thoma has put together quite a startling list of the five members of the board of governors of the Federal Reserve as well as the twelve district bank presidents. Of those seventeen individuals, just one, William Poole, was appointed by under a Democratic administration. Still, says Thoma:

I don’t want to imply that the Fed is driven by politics or ideology, because (now that Greenspan is gone?) it isn’t.

Certainly with names like Tim Geithner on the list, one can hardly complain that all of the appointees have been Republicans. (Geithner was a political appointee at Treasury during the Clinton administration.) And even people who object to the Fed’s decisions don’t think that they’ve been made in an attempt to prop up the Bush administration.

It seems to me that the world of finance in general is much less politicized than any other area of government, and that attempts to politicize it generally fail miserably. Clearly there’s a lot of politics surrounding the area of fiscal policy concerned with tax cuts. And there might be a very weak correlation between the hawk-dove spectrum and the Republican-Democrat spectrum. But it’s very easy to think of Republican doves and Democratic hawks. And the Fed, in particular, seems to have done a very good job of remaining genuinely independent, which is one reason why Greenspan’s testimony in favor of the Bush tax cuts was so very shocking.

Posted in fiscal and monetary policy, Politics | Comments Off on The Political Independence of the Fed

Why It’s Safe to Bet Against Joe Lewis

Are you tantalized by the prospect of Slate’s new business site? Well, the editor, Jim Ledbetter, is guest-blogging over at Fortune today, so maybe that will give you an idea of what to expect. This morning, talking about the Bear Stearns share price, he lays out the good arguments why Bear shares won’t end up being worth any more than $2 a share, despite the fact that Joe Lewis and others are unhappy about that deal. But then he suddenly reverses himself:

Even if their plan is a long shot, you could lose a lot of money betting against furious billionaires hellbent on protecting their assets.

I don’t see why or how you could lose a lot of money betting on Bear stock going down; after all, betting against these furious billionaires has been stunningly successful up until now.

Ledbetter seems to think that Lewis can find common cause with Bear employees, who own 30% of the stock. But those employees have one overriding concern right now, and that’s their jobs. Jamie Dimon is offering cash and stock to Bear employees if they support the takeover: that’s an offer which isn’t being extended to Joe Lewis, but is pretty attractive when the alternative is hoping that a bankruptcy will end up with some residual value for shareholders. Even employees who get fired will make out better than Lewis:

Bear Stearns employees not offered a job by JPMorgan will receive cash payouts of 25 percent to 35 percent of their 2006 compensation provided they stay until the deal is completed, Dimon said, according to the two people. JPMorgan hasn’t decided how many employees it will retain.

So it’s far from obvious that Lewis has Bear’s employees on his side, even putting aside the fact that Bear’s executives, who own extremely large chunks of stock, will also receive hugely valuable indemnification against lawsuits if the acquisition goes through.

Ledbetter also seems to think that there’s some small hope of shareholders getting money at the end of a bankruptcy proceeding:

My understanding is that, in order to shun the JPMorgan offer, the company would have to declare bankruptcy, and in bankruptcy the shareholders have to get in line behind other creditors, thus by no means guaranteeing a better outcome than $2 a share.

By no means guaranteeing a better outcome? Bankruptcy guarantees a worse outcome. If Bear goes into bankruptcy, there wouldn’t be some nice indefinite Chapter 11 proceeding where the company can be operated as a going concern and eventually sold for a large sum of money. No, broker-dealers have to file for Chapter 7 liquidation, where Bear’s assets would be dumped unceremoniously onto a market which clearly has no capacity to buy them all. That’s what the Fed was trying to avoid, and that’s why bankruptcy would result in no money at all for shareholders. (Matt Miller and John Blakeley explained this in the Deal on Monday, in an article which unfortunately isn’t online.)

The best hope for Lewis is not bankruptcy, but rather that he can somehow put together a credible better offer for Bear himself – one which would be accepted by a majority of shareholders even if JP Morgan exercises its option to buy 20% of the company at $2 a share, and one which would somehow manage to get the blessing of the Fed, which is solidly in Jamie Dimon’s camp. Even Ledbetter doesn’t see that happening; for all the gory details of why it won’t happen, see Heidi Moore.

I see only one conceivable way in which Bear gets taken over for much more than $2 a share (or a bit more than that now, as the offer is in stock, and JP Morgan’s stock has risen since the offer was made). And that’s if Jamie Dimon unilaterally decides to raise his offer, deciding that spending a couple of hundred million dollars more on the acquisition is worth it if it avoids months of legal headaches. And Dimon’s said quite explicitly that he won’t do that. In this deal, Dimon’s the winner, and Lewis is the loser. If you want to bet on the loser, feel free. But don’t expect to make any money doing so.

Posted in banking, stocks | Comments Off on Why It’s Safe to Bet Against Joe Lewis

Will Burglaries Rise in a Credit Crunch?

The world of stolen goods, like any other market, is in thrall to the dynamics of supply and demand. The supply comes from burglars, who burgle houses and steal goods. The demand comes from a much more disparate and less well-defined group, who can to a first approximation be considered "people who want stuff they can’t afford".

It turns out that as demand for stolen goods has been falling, the incidence of burglaries has been falling too, just as you’d expect. But what happens now? There’s a case to be made that "people who want stuff they can’t afford" have found it easier, in recent years, to just go out and buy that stuff legally, putting it on their credit cards and then paying off their plastic with home-equity loans. (See: the world’s scariest chart.) But in a credit crunch, people can’t do that any more. So will they revert to buying stolen goods? And will burglaries therefore start rising, for the first time in 30 years?

(Via Cowen)

Posted in economics | Comments Off on Will Burglaries Rise in a Credit Crunch?

The Housing Crunch Without Houses

In an interactive feature of mine earlier this month, the most bubblicious bubble of them all was Astana, the new capital of Kazakhstan. Well, it seems to be bursting already: Bloomberg is running the wonderful headline "Kazakhs Get Craters, Not Homes as Credit Crunch Halts Builders" on a story which reports that a $4 billion emergency government investment program is trying to buy up 6,000 uncompleted apartments in the capital. And things are just as bad in the former capital, Almaty, where 140 housing projects have been halted and 29,000 people have paid for apartments which haven’t been built. So, if you’re suffering under the burden of negative equity right now, at least be thankful that your home exists.

(Via Krugman)

Posted in emerging markets, housing | Comments Off on The Housing Crunch Without Houses